Parties’ reasonable expectations in this type of K 132
The usual consequences of breach 132
Evidence (if any) of commercial expectations – how are the risks usually assigned? 132
Did the parties explicitly address the risk? 132
Mitigation 132
Basics 133
must take reasonable steps to minimize the damages from ∆ breach 133
In sale of goods cases, the mitigation requirement is basically codified: 133
S. 53 – Damages for Nonacceptance 133
(1) If the buyer wrongfully neglects or refuses to accept and pay for the goods, the seller may maintain an action against the buyer for damages for nonacceptance. 133
(2) The measure of damages is the estimated loss directly and naturally resulting, in the ordinary course of events, from the buyer’s breach of K. 133
(3) If there is an available market for the goods in question, the measure of damages is to be ascertained (unless there is evidence to the contrary) by the difference between the K price and the market or current price at the time or times when the goods ought to have been accepted, or if no time was set for acceptance, then at the time of refusal to accept. 133
S. 54 – Damages for Nondelivery 133
(1) If the seller wrongfully neglects or refuses to deliver the goods to the buyer, the buyer may maintain an action against the seller for damages for nondelivery. 133
(2) The measure of damages is the estimated loss directly and naturally resulting, in the ordinary course of events, from the seller's breach of contract. 133
(3) If there is an available market for the goods in question, the measure of damages is to be ascertained, unless there is evidence to the contrary, by the difference between the contract price and the market or current price of the goods at the time or times when they ought to have been delivered, or, if no time was set, then at the time of the refusal to deliver. 133
Cockburn v. Trusts Guarantee Co. 133
Facts 133
Company went into liquidation, ∆ wrongfully dismissed & sues for lost wages. 133
Salary at time of dismissal: $5000/year 133
bought a bunch of stuff at the company’s liquidation sale, and sold it for $11k 133
Issue: did mitigate out of any damages? 133
∆ argued used his time to make profit, which he wouldn’t have been able to do if ≠ dismissed. 133
argued ≠ mitigation because it goes beyond what an employee would be expected to do. He became an entrepreneur/speculator. Didn’t have to do this. 133
Held: mitigated out of damages 133
Reasons 133
Although ≠ required to mitigate in that way, the ability to make that money resulted from the breach of K – could not have happened but for the breach. 134
First, he got the inventory because the company went into liquidation. 134
Second, he had the time to buy/sell the inventory because the company dismissed him as a result of the liquidation. 134
Apeco v. Windmill 134
Facts: 134
owns warehouse; ∆ agrees to lease part for 5 years 134
∆ breaches, finds new tenant. 134
sues ∆ for 5 years of rent, but ∆ says they mitigated by renting to the new tenant. 134
Held: is entitled to the lost rent from ∆ 134
Reasons: 134
Distinguishable from Cockburn: yes, they had found a new tenant, but ¾ of the warehouse was vacant. If ∆ had stayed, the new tenant would have been in addition to ∆ - not instead. 134
So, in this case the second transaction hasn’t mitigated the loss suffered by . 134
Assess by considering causation: did the breach cause or permit the new transaction with subsequent benefit? 134
i.e. is the second transaction dependent on or independent of the breach? 134
Erie County Natural Gas v. Carroll [HL] 134
Facts 134
π manufacturer of quicklime. 8 year lease of gas rights on π property to ∆ gas co, w/ req’mt to supply π with gas. 134
∆ sold the lease to a third party, who ≠ supply gas. 134
π built their own structure to obtain gas on their remaining portion of the property, at a cost of $60k. 134
At the end of the 8 year period, π sold the gas works for $75k. 134
π claimed the expenditure to get the gas, and also $125k for the cost of their own gas used 134
Held: No award to π. 134
Reasons 134
π mitigated by selling the structure for $75k. 134
Also, court said it would be unfair to award the additional $125k value of the gas consumed, because then π would profit from ∆’s breach. One Lord called this a “grotesque” result. 134
Comments: 134
However, the question re mitigation is really supposed to be whether the breach caused/permitted the earnings, and in this case it did not. 134
πs were tapping into their own gas, which was always there and which could have been done regardless of ∆ behaviour. 134
Jamal v. Moola Dawood Sons & Co. [1916, PC (Burma)] 135
Facts 135
∆ backed out of share sale w/ π 135
K price was $184,000 rupees. As a result of breach, π only got $75,000 rs. 135
π held shares past breach date, then made a series of sales that cumulatively brought in $200,000. (So, higher price than K would have brought in, even) 135
Held: π did not mitigate out of damages, ∆ still obligated to pay. 135
Damages are measured at time of breach. 135
Waiting is at π risk, and if π is found to have mitigated out of damages by waiting and selling at a higher price, then ∆s should also be responsible if π waits and is forced to sell at lower price. 135
π can do whatever he wants after breach, but it’s at his own risk. 135
Conceptually, π could have gone through with first K and then later bought and sold shares again independently shares are fungible. 135
Distinct from Cockburn, in which π could not have done what he did but for the breach. 135
Campbell Mostyn v. Barnett Trading 135
There may be a class of cases in which it is impossible to resell goods – e.g. because there is no market. 135
Issue: ∆ argued that market price of ham at time of breach was very good – trying to minimize their damages on basis that π could have mitigated out of all damage. 135
But then later, on appeal, ∆ argued that there was no available market at time of breach, and damages should thus be assessed on the price 6 months after the breach. 135
Held: not impossible to resell goods, viable market existed. 135
The two arguments made by ∆ cannot be reconciled, and the Court of Appeal caught this contradiction in finding that there was a viable market. 135
Time of Assessment 135
General principle: courts assess damages at time of breach. 135
Further changes in price and increases in costs after the time of breach are typically not relevant 135
But, there are some exceptions: 135
Asamera Oil Corp. v. Sea Oil and General Corp. [1979, SCC] 135
Facts 135
π loaned shares to ∆, ≠ returned on time, and much later π and court discovered that they were sold to a third party. 135
Issue: how to assess damages when shares were never returned, and varied in value? 135
π wanted highest list price of the shares in the time ∆ held them, but they were worth far less at time of breach. 135
π argued sophisticated commercial actor, would have sold shares at highest price. 136
π sought specific performance and damages. 136
Held: Court awards damages according to a mid-range share price. 136
Reasons 136
Court accepts that π might have sold shares at higher value than at date of breach, but not so high that they would get the full highest price. 136
1. Court endorses theory of damages put forward by π; damages are measured by the lost opportunity to sell the shares – i.e. to realize their value on sale. 136
2. The typical starting point for damages under a loan is at the time of breach. You assess as though π had disposed of property on the date of breach, or as soon after as they were realistically able to do so. 136
3. Sometimes, though, we will move the date of breach. 136
4. If π is seeking/entitled to specific performance, they are entitled to hold off on mitigation, so long as they have a real/substantial interest in specific performance. 136
Just because it’s in your writ doesn’t mean it’s a real/substantial interest. 136
Typically can’t get SP for shares – they’re fungible. 136
5. πs may also be entitled to hold off on mitigation depending on the state of the market (e.g. volatile or illiquid) reasonableness depends on context 136
Even though ≠SP, π was entitled to wait before buying new shares. Successfully argued it wouldn’t be reasonable to go buy new shares right away, due to the illiquidity of the market. 136
π argued they didn’t have to mitigate because shares were too risky now, but they had wanted SP. So, if they wouldn’t have bought the shares, they wouldn’t have held the shares, so those arguments contradict in a rational commercial sense. (Supposedly.) 136
Dodd Properties v. Canterbury City Council [Eng. CA] 136
Facts 136
Two neighbouring buildings, one damaged during construction. 136
Value ↓ over time, by ~£30k 136
π wanted damages calculated at the later date, to account for the decline in value. 136
Held: damages assessed at later date 136
Reasons: 136
There will always be some reasonable period in which for π to organize finances, arrange contractors etc to move on from the breached K. 136
Court allowed the π to wait 8 years in this case, during which time the cost of repairs massively increased. 136
πs argued it wasn’t reasonable for them to put their own $ at risk doing repairs at earlier date, for several reasons (none of which are especially convincing): 136
1. ∆s were denying liability 137
That’s sort of ridiculous, since ∆s deny liability all the time and it doesn’t typically let you off the hook for mitigation. 137
Maybe because it was government, in this case? Not at all clear from the judgment, though. 137
2. πs didn’t want to spend their own money because (a) they had a cash problem, and (b) even if they didn’t, director testified that they still wouldn’t have spent the money before they were sure of recovering cost from ∆. 137
This is a dangerous argument: recall Radford v. DeFroberville: intent to do the work is key in whether π can recover. So, in their anti-mitigation argument, π here actually led evidence that undercuts their main argument. 137
∆ argued they shouldn’t have to pay full amount of lost business. Since it’s less than 100% likely that they will actually experience loss because they may not conduct the repairs, ∆ argued for 60%. 137
Perry v. Sidney Philips [1982, Eng. CA] 137
Facts 137
Defective property – surveyor ∆ failed to detect the defect. 137
π couldn’t afford to properly repair the defect at the time it was discovered. 137
π claimed cost of repairs, and also damages for the physical inconvenience and stress of living in a crappy house (full of mould etc.) for 4 years as a result of the negligent survey. 137
Held: CA refused to award cost of repairs. Instead, awarded damages based on difference between cost paid and reasonable cost knowing about the defect. However, he gets the physical inconvenience b/c he had to stick with it due to impecuniosity (and no failure to mitigate) 137
Reasons 137
1. Surveyor didn’t cause the defect negligent survey just caused a delay in the discovery of the damage, meaning that π spent a bit more on the property because he didn’t know about the defect. 137
Hence, π gets difference between cost paid and cost he should have paid given the defects. 137
2. Impecuniosity claim allowed 137
Consumer case, not commercial 137
Part of the reason people use a surveyor is to avoid financial risk 137
The key: is it within the scope of the K? (i.e., what is the K about?) 137
This is not a risk that π could have protected himself against. 137
No insurance for hidden defects 137
The way you protect against this is by hiring a surveyor. 137
Damages in Lieu of Specific Performance 137
Issue: these arise when π claims specific performance up to trial, then drops the SP claim at trial. 138
Wroth v. Tyler [1974, Eng.] 138
Facts: 138
House price: £6000. ∆ breached K for sale; π sued for SP. 138
At time of breach, house was worth £7500. At trial, worth £11,500. 138
So, damages at time of breach = £1500. But if real and substantial claim for SP, damages in lieu would be £5500. 138
Held: court awards damages in lieu of SP, totaling £5500 138
Reasons 138
Court wouldn’t grant SP, because it would cause husband to sue wife over charge, or SP subject to wife’s occupation rights. 138
You can’t get SP where it would require a third party to waive their legal rights. 138
But, where π has a legitimate claim for SP, damages should be calculated in lieu. 138
Principle: π couldn’t mitigate, and reasonably didn’t, because they expected SP. So, court can push the time of assessment right up to trial. 138
Problem: people will always throw in a claim for SP even if they don’t want it, to push time of assessment. But must be real & substantial interest. 138
Semelhago v. Paramadevan [1996, SCC] 138
SCC adopts Asamera and Wroth. 138
Courts will take a different approach to damages and mitigation where there is a real and substantial interest in specific performance. 138
Facts: 138
House under construction at time of K. Purchase price = $205k 138
At time of trial, worth $325k 138
π was going to buy the house with $75k cash plus mortgage of $135, then sell their old house for $190k. Value of old house at time of trial = $300k. 138
So, if no breach: up by $114k between -6000 mortgage and +120k on (new) house. 138
Held: 138
Damages in lieu of SP 138
Result of judgment: 138
New house: +$120k; 138
Old house: +$110k; 138
Return on the $75k not spent: $20k; 138
So, up by a total of $250k. 138
Reasons 138
Court says you can’t deduct the increase in value to the old house, but they let the reduction in mortgage costs stand because it wasn’t argued. Yes, it is a windfall, but SP would have been too. 138
Note: later cases have resiled from this a bit. 139
Picks up line from Asamera: need real and substantial interest to rely on SP claim to get damages in lieu. 139
Specific Performance in Real Estate Ks 139
Background 139
This is important because of Asamera and Semelhago, which tell us that courts will take a different approach to damages and mitigation where there is a real and substantial interest in specific performance. 139
So, we need to know how to assess whether someone has a real and substantial interest in SP. 139
Up to a few years ago, SP was the prima facie rule in real estate Ks 139
There was a presumption that land is unique, damages inadequate and thus that SP would always be available 139
Consumer surplus element, esp. w/ residential land. 139
It’s not just about living situation in UK especially, land was key to social status for a long time. 139
Changes (see Domowicz; Semelhago; Asamera): 139
(1) Land is no longer key to voting, status, civic rights 139
(2) It’s often not unique 139
Land is often bought as a commercial investment, even when it’s residential 139
Many people flip houses or otherwise buy land just to make revenue things that can be measured in money. 139
(3) Even residential property is no longer really unique 139
Cookie cutter homes, many substitutes for the same property 139
(4) Courts: preference for damages goal is to put people in as good a position but not better, and damages achieve this better than SP. 139
Problem of uncertainty about SP in real estate: it’s more difficult to advise clients now. 139
Domowicz v. Orsa Investments Ltd. [1993, ON Gen. Div.] 139
Most comprehensive analysis of this issue. 139
Fact: Bought apartment building in a suburb w/ 7 year delay. 139
Held: No SP. 139
Reasons 139
The longer the delay, the less likely a court will grant SP. 139
Asamera: “mitigate or litigate” – either mitigate to protect against escalating damages award, or get to litigating quickly so you minimize the possibility of price increases 139
SCC in Domowicz adopts this statement in obiter. 139
No damages in lieu of SP only get those if you have a legitimate distinct interest in SP. 139
McNabb v. Smith [1982, BCCA] 140
Applied Domowicz to residential purchase 140
∆ showed evidence that planned to flip house – not entitled to SP. 140
At time of breach, buyer had already entered into transaction to sell the property for more than his purchase price. So, damages could fully compensate for his loss. 140
Semelhago v. Paramadevan [1996, SCC] (continued) 140
Facts: Residential Development 140
Held: No SP, sort of. 140
TJ gave SP, but SCC says in obiter that SP shouldn’t have been granted – i.e. it wouldn’t have been available if it had been in issue on the appeal 140
SCC also says that you don’t presumptively give SP with land anymore. 140
Huge windfall to of a damages award calculated in lieu of SP. Issue of hardship to ∆, who ended up paying ~125k more in cash damages than actually lost. (b/c kept own home and avoided mortgage and carrying costs etc.) 140
Court is balancing necessity of protecting w/ order for SP (weak) with a desire to protect ∆ against undue/oppressive amt of damages (strong) inclines against SP. 140
John E. Dodge Holdings Ltd. v. 805062 Ontario Ltd. [2001, ONSC] 140
Facts: 140
= hotel builder/manager. Agreement to purchase land (vacant lot) from ∆ co. 140
Agreement req’d severance approval from city before proceeding. City granted approval, subj to possibility that ∆ might be req’d to construct an extension to a nearby road & dedicate it to city. Cost was set b/w $350-500k. 140
Building the road would not have benefited or ∆, only other property owners. 140
∆ tried to get out of the agreement; sued for specific performance. 140
Legal Issues: Specific performance – is performance of the K unique? Since Sopinka’s dissent in Semelhago, courts don’t assume that about land Ks anymore. 140
Held: SP awarded 140
Reasons: 140
This particular transaction merited SP, damages would be inadequate. 140
Land was right next to a mall and Wonderland, so that was a specific attribute. 140
Evidence that they had tried to find a substitute but couldn’t find one that replicated all the features of the desired land. 140
Note: It would be highly speculative to calculate the damages in a monetary sense 140
SP is granted where damages are inadequate (i.e. it’s not just about money), but also where it is all about money but damages are too difficult to calculate. 140
Earthworks 2000 Design Group Inc. v. Spectacular Investments (Canada) [2005, BCSC] 140
Facts: Convenience store 140
Held: you can build a gas station w/ convenience store pretty much anywhere. Damages ≠ inadequate. Not a unique or complicated business model like in Dodge. 141
Raymond v. Raymond Estate [2011, SKCA] 141
Facts: Farmland dispute. owned part interest in land and K’d w/ ∆ for another portion. 141
Held: SP granted. 141
Reasons 141
Personal reasons why ownership of this particular family farm was unique. 141
Note, though, that farming is generally a commercial operation, so must look at rel’ship b/w ∆ and the property in question. Is it really tied to the family thing or is it just that he needs to expand? 141
TJ refused SP on grounds that he suspected real interest in property wasn’t unique, but that it was actually part of a long-standing family feud in which he was seeking retribution against his siblings. 141
CA: that’s irrelevant, so long as we also believe he wanted this particular piece of property. 141
See list of factors at pg. 1029. 141
Proximity – yardsite for his cattle 141
Emotional attachment to the land (accepted) 141
Right across the road from his house 141
Measurement Issues: Reinstatement or Diminution 141
Damage to Chattels 141
Dewees v. Morrow [1932, BCCA] 141
Cost of repair: $1458 141
Cost of replacement: $900 141
Court says only entitled to cost of reasonable substitute, not cost of repair 141
Darbishire v. Warran [1963, Eng. CA] 141
Repair: £192 141
Replacement: £85 141
Same as Dewees - not entitled to cost of repair where that cost exceeds that of a reasonable substitute. 141
BUT: 141
O’Grady v. Westminster Scaffolding Ltd. [1962, QB] 141
Repair: £253 141
Replacement: £180-250 141
Held: entitled to repair even though repair costs exceed reasonable cost of substitute. 141
Reasons: 141
Personal attachment to the car. 142
had named it, replaced the engine three times already 142
So, he had shown that he was willing to spend the $, and that he HAD done the work. 142
Remember the policy from DeFroberville: if wouldn’t do the work otherwise or isn’t actually going to do the work now, shouldn’t be entitled to make ∆ pay for it. 142
Price was close to repair cost. 142
Note: monetary value of the wasn’t fully ascertainable, as it kept appreciating due to status as classic car. 142
Plus, court noted that it was difficult to find a reasonable substitute given the condition he had kept it in. 142
Note that was NOT allowed to claim for 5 months of rental cars while waiting to have car repaired. 142
Duty to mitigate; goes to time of assessment. 142
Court did make a deduction from the repair costs for betterment – the car was in slightly better condition than before, and avoided 5 months worth of wear-and-tear/depreciation, thus increasing its value. 142
Factors to Consider Re Reinstatement for Damage to Chattels: 142
Damage to Real Property 142
Taylor v. Hepworths Ltd. 142
Facts: owned shops & billiards hall. ∆ caused fire and property is basically destroyed. claimed cost of rebuilding the hall. 142
Held: Not awarded. 142
Reasons 142
did not actually intend to rebuild the hall it was only an investment property, and rebuilding would not have been a good investment 142
Basically, there was no diminution in value because was going to have to tear down the building to redevelop the site. 142
So, really, he saved money by not having to pay for the tear-down. 142
Jens v. Mannix & Co. [1978, BCSC] 142
Facts: Oil spill makes house uninhabitable; will have to dig up overburden and replace all contaminated soil, then build entirely new house. Property could likely be sold for more w/o house, since zoned commercially and has greater value as such. 142
Held: full value of repairs awarded by TJ; CA reduced for betterment. 142
Reasons 143
actually lives there and wants to stay. 143
It’s like the factors discussed in Dodge: 143
has proximity to car museum in which he keeps his cars 143
Local community likes it and gave exemption to have the museum on his property 143
Basically, has a credible, proven subjective attachment to this particular property, which can’t easily be replicated. 143
Note: this would have been a tough case to argue: 143
He hadn’t actually rebuilt the house if he had done so, it would show real intention to do the work 143
Failure to rebuild leaves judges a bit nervous because he put up with the problem for 4 years, may not use the award to rebuild and may sell the land instead, garnering a windfall. 143
This is probably why they scaled back the award. 143
Betterment 143
Old house; tearing it down and building new one gives an advantage, so court makes a 10% deduction for betterment and also deducts an amount for the increase in building costs over the 4 year delay. 143
Kates v. Hall [1991, BCCA] 143
Facts: ∆ cut down several mature trees on property to get better view. Cost of replacement with fully grown trees (which may not even take) is $210k, but no diminution in value of property. 143
Issue: Neither amount is really appealing. The question is: what interest of the is the court seeking to protect? 143
Held: Court crafted a 3-part award, tied to this policy question. 143
1. Repair interest: $21,000 to plant a bunch of smaller trees w/ greater likelihood of flourishing. 143
Because the trees do serve an important esthetic/privacy purpose, part of the award should be to spend a reasonable amount on repairs. 143
This takes care of some repairs, but doesn’t address the functional interest 143
2. Functional interest: $1000/tree for lost amenity 143
Subjective value of having nice, full-grown trees 143
3. Punitive damages: $26,000 to deter ∆ behaviour 143
$210k would be too much, but some punitive amount is necessary to address the egregious and flagrant breach – intentional trespass and cutting down trees to make own property go up in value. 143
Court could have awarded higher punitive damages, but: 143
Judge thought was just after retribution. 143
Plus, didn’t even really live there – just a few weeks a year; and they owned 8 homes each worth multi-millions. 143
If you look at the overall award as punitive damages, 60k is pretty high. 144
Betterment 144
General Principle: we deduct windfall amounts of increased value to property resulting from repairs 144
James St. Hardware v. Spizziri [1987, ONCA] 144
Facts: 144
Cites similar old UK HL case (Harbotts Plasticine): 144
factory burned down by ∆; replaced and updated to code etc. Got more valuable factory as a result; court refused to deduct for betterment in that case. Not fair that ∆ torched factory and forced into that situation, and not fair to make spend own money on the repairs. Lord Denning: destruction of bldg isn’t the same as of car – can go into market and get a new car, but when mill was destroyed company had to replace it. 144
Factory burned down and had to build to better std b/c of building codes. Plus getting extra years out of factory 144
Held: 144
Court accepts (but does not apply) Waddams’ argument: 144
Courts should deduct for betterment, then add back in the opportunity costs of the money (this was done in Safe Steps) 144
Safe Steps 144
Calculate deduction for betterment by taking betterment value [how much it will increase] and subtracting from that the interest on the amount it will cost to do the repairs. 144
Assumption: you can borrow the money to do the repairs, so only the interest is counted against the betterment value. If you don’t get a loan, it’s assumed that you would have invested the money on a rate of return approximately equivalent to the bank’s interest rate. 144
Fontaine v. Roofmart Western Ltd. [2005, MBQB] 144
Facts: Shingles deteriorated before expected; had to replace. But they did last for 10 years. 144
Issue: if awarded full value of new shingles, getting a windfall for those 10 years’ coverage. But had to spend own money 5 years earlier than expected. 144
Held: court awarded 5 years of the value of the shingles (but actually only 2 years because it took a while to replace the shingles) 144
Looked at opportunity costs over time the advance was made by , and amount of money spent. 144
Betterment: 10 years. 144
III. Remedies for Personal Injury 145
Context: The Role of Tort in Dealing with Disability 145
Theoretical Basis 145
Compensation, deterrence, corrective justice, dispute resolution 145
Is tort the best way to achieve these goals? Alternatives? 145
Itemizing Damages 145
There must be a rationale for why particular heads of compensation are used, and in what amounts. 145
Tort law can act as a junior partner in injury response. Other sources include: 145
Workers compensation: 145
Public compensation scheme, available in every province; provides compensation to people injured in the course of employment 145
Vastly most significant than tort law in providing compensation. 145
Plus, worker’s comp is exclusive/exhaustive it’s a complete system; can’t go to worker’s comp then move to claim in tort law as well. 145
Provincial health insurance 145
Automobile insurance – first party no-fault benefits 145
People buy liability insurance, to cover them in the event that someone is injured, but we also have first party benefits to give compensation if the driver is injured. 145
This helps keep smaller injuries out of court, reducing transaction costs of providing compensation. 145
Private disability insurance 145
Public disability plans (pensions): EI, social welfare, CPP 145
Tort as a problematic mechanism for addressing injury/disability. 145
See Dickson J’s comments in Andrews, at pg. 492. 145
Efficiency: litigation is uncertain, time consuming and expensive. 145
Tort provides uneven coverage. 145
Tort in the world of insurance does not promote deterrence 145
Occasional spectacular lump sum awards highlight: 145
(a) moral arbitrariness 145
(b) pragmatic problems for prediction and management 145
Andrews (The “Trilogy”): Overview of Methodology 145
SCC dealt with three cases at once: 145
Andrews v. Grand & Toy; Teno; Thornton v. Prince George School 145
Court came very close to legislating in these decisions. 145
Set out a highly systematic approach to personal injury damages 145
Special (past) damages 145
General (future) damages – itemize for appellate review and settlement predictability. 145
Cost of care, standard of care, predictions. 145
Collateral benefits – how are these addressed? 145
Taxation: 146
(a) deducted from lost earnings? 146
(b) add-on for impact on award? 146
Discounting to a lump sum 146
Management fees, structured settlements 146
Lump Sums: Finality vs. Accuracy 146
Advantages and Disadvantages 146
See Dickson J’s comments in Andrews at pg. 492 146
Courts need to consider the amount needed for annual support over a lifetime, but also how spending power will be reduced over time. 146
Shifting needs are an issue – a lump sum is a once-and-for-all decision. 146
Andrews, 21, has a remaining life span of 43 years, and is awarded $740k to provide for his needs over the next 43 years. 146
BUT, we don’t know what his needs will be over that whole time period. We sort of need to, though… 146
Contingencies 146
How courts deal with uncertainty and future changes. 146
Discounting 146
How courts deal with future changes in the value of money 146
Theoretical basis: 146
Discount rate is a percentage that takes into account the combined effect of investment earnings and inflation. 146
A dollar today is worth more than a dollar tomorrow. 146
Theory: future value must take into account the negative effects of inflation, and the positive effects of compound interest. 146
Rule from the Trilogy: subtract inflation (3%) from interest rates (10%) to determine the discount rate (so, 7%). 146
So, to give $100/year: 146
Need $100 this year, 93 next year (100% minus 7%), 87 the following year (93% minus 7%), 81 the next year, and so on. 146
The Trilogy Mistake: 146
The inflation rate was higher than the court anticipated, and the difference meant that the assumed rate of return was basically halved. 146
Data in 1975: 146
Inflation: 10% 146
Long term inflation forecast: 3.5% 146
Long term bonds: $10% 146
So, to produce $100 in 45 years: 146
7% = $4.76 147
3% = $26.44 147
$500,000 lump sum for 45 years (per Andrews) 147
7% = $34,346/year 147
3% = $19,798/year 147
Law and Equity Act 147
Corrects the error and facilitates settlement and adjudication 147
Discount Rates: s. 56 147
(1) in this section: 147
“discount rate” means the rate, expressed as a percentage, used in calculating the present value of future damages. 147
“future damages” means damages to compensate for pecuniary losses to be incurred, or expenditures to be made, after the date of the trial judgment in a proceeding. 147
(2) The Chief Justice of the Supreme Court may make regulations prescribing: 147
(a) the discount rate that is deemed to be the future difference between the investment rate of interest and the rate of increase of earnings due to inflation and general increases in productivity, and… [2.5% for future earnings] 147
(b) the discount rate that is deemed to be the future difference between the investment rate of interest and the rate of general price inflation. [3.5% for cost of care] 147
(3) In a proceeding, the discount rate prescribed under (2)(a) must be used in calculating the present value of future damages that are intended to compensate for or are determined with reference to 147
(a) loss of earnings because of partial or total loss of income-earning capacity, or 147
(b) loss of dependency under the Family Compensation Act 147
(4) The discount rate prescribed under (2)(b) must be used in calculating the present value of all future damages other than those referred to in (3). 147
Non-Pecuniary Losses 147
The conundrum: money can’t buy happiness. Pain and suffering is not commensurable (can’t be measured in money) 147
Issue: how do we compensate something with money that can’t really be measured in money? 147
The old approach: pain & suffering, lost amenities or enjoyment of life, lost expectation of life all awarded with general arbitrary sum 147
The “Insurance Crisis”: 147
Sense that tort awards were getting out of control. 147
Courts’ approach in personal injury cases didn’t lend itself to predictability. 147
Judges and juries were just tossing out numbers and it was difficult to see the parameters for an award. 148
Uncertainty bred a litigation explosion – can’t settle if you don’t even know what the range of damages is. 148
Dramatic escalations in auto insurance premiums 148
Defensive medicine: 148
Doctors fleeing North America to practice in jurisdictions where the fear of tort litigation wasn’t so high. 148
Changing medical practice b/c doctors were always trying to protect against liability. 148
Public services and amenities (schools, parks) 148
Rash of closures of fun playground equipment, ridiculously overprotective safety measures put in because of the fear of liability/increased costs. 148
Media focus on spectacular awards 148
New Theoretical Basis – The Functional Approach 148
As Opposed To: 148
The Conceptual Approach 148
Trying to capture human facilities and ascribe costs to them 148
Sometimes described as a “meat chart” approach. Injury, and a dollar value associated therewith. 148
Does get some certainty, but not the best. 148
The Personal Approach 148
Developments on the conceptual approach: take the same chart, but personalize it. 148
A hand injury to one person might not be as serious as to another, depending on their personal circumstances. 148
E.g. a pianist’s hands are arguably more valuable. 148
Lends itself to ‘invidious’ comparisons comparability problems between injuries and consequent awards. 148
Basics of the Functional Approach 148
Consideration: not so much the category of the injury, but the way that injury affects π’s life, and the way in which money can be used to replace/address what was lost. 148
Substituting one imperfect system of measurement for other imperfect systems. 148
The Cap 148
Controls social costs. 148
In Andrews, the court imposed a rough upper limit: 148
Unless in exceptional circumstances, the max award in this category is $100k. 148
This was done explicitly on the basis of the insurance crisis social costs can be taken into account here as a matter of policy, to maintain some regulation on those costs. 148
The ‘rough upper limit’ really operates as a cap – no courts have made awards above it. 149
Note inflationary increase: as of October 2012 the upper limit is about $342k. 149
Logical Conclusions of the Functional Approach 149
Not based on severity of the injury, but on ability to use money [See Lindal at para 17] 149
The same injury in two different people will likely have different non-pecuniary losses. 149
Issues: lost years, age 149
Unconscious or vegetative π [see Wipfli; Tonneguzzo; Brimacombe; Bystedt] 149
Consistency? Factors? 149
Factors to consider in compensating for non-pecuniary loss in a brain injury case: 149
Ability to appreciate what has been lost 149
E.g. experience pleasure, pain, enjoyment, sadness 149
Attempts to communicate 149
Attentional abilities 149
Memories 149
Life expectancy 149
Problems with the Canadian Approach 149
Berryman et al 149
The functional approach isn’t really applied in practice. 149
So, basically, everyone talks about the functional approach, but then everyone runs to the meat charts and uses them anyway. 149
The cap doesn’t apply to aggravated damages in other areas 149
E.g. defamation (Hill), debate re sexual assault cases 149
This appears to create anomalies 149
Problem of compression/relative unfairness 149
Any award above the cap will be overturned. 149
The cap is meant to be reached only by really extreme injuries, etc. 149
Most personal injury cases aren’t about quadriplegia, they’re about whiplash and broken bones, etc. 149
But, awards for these things are creeping up. 149
So, the cap really just means that catastrophic cases aren’t getting much in comparison – not much (if anything) more than the basic injury cases 149
Because of the lack of regulatory scaling, the real costs of insurance and litigation are resulting from these minor injuries. 149
Chaos below the cap: no jury direction, no scale, no consistency 149
Technically, no one uses the word “cap” – judgments still call it the rough upper limit. 149
But no case has ever exceeded that limit, so it’s really a solid ceiling on non-pecuniary damages for personal injury. 149
Alternatives 149
Take the functional approach seriously 150
Remove cap entirely and leave it to juries 150
English model: common law conceptual approach with guidance 150
Australian model: statutory scale based on severity 150
Start at the top (most catastrophic) and scale down. 150
So, e.g. quadriplegia = 100% of cap awarded, then lesser amounts depending on severity of injury 150
This model may encourage settlement (since it makes it easy to calculate damages), meaning there will actually be more money for πs (since less money spent on litigation) 150
Eliminate non-pecuniary damages altogether in personal injury cases 150
Money would be reallocated to other purposes 150
New Zealand has essentially abolished the tort system: 150
Statutory no-fault compensation scheme. Small amounts on non-pecuniary side, but uses the savings to provide compensation to a much broader class of things on the pecuniary side. 150
Pecuniary Losses: Lost Future Earnings 150
Issue: 150
It’s easy to quantify the lost earnings up to trial: the actual amount of money that was lost as a result of not being able to work. 150
BUT: it’s tougher to determine what future earnings would have been. 150
Theoretical basis: (see Cooper-Stevenson) 150
Lost actual earnings 150
Lost earning capacity 150
Lost working capacity 150
Step 1: Estimate the level of earnings 150
Probable earnings plus chances [Andrews] 150
Step 2: Consider length of working life 150
Pre-accident lifespan and estimated retirement date 150
Important: lost future earnings are based on pre-accident lifespan the total amount π might have earned. 150
Note: we used to estimate that people would retire around 65, unless other factors impacted it. But now that mandatory retirement has been eliminated, parties get into arguments about this more often. 150
Complicating feature: the issue of lost years 150
Example: A 20 year old is catastrophically injured, and prior to the accident would have worked until 65. As a result of the accident, lifespan shortened by 20 years, such that they will die at 45. 150
Lost earnings will be calculated on the basis of pre-accident lifespan, and from that award π is supposed to pay costs of living while they live, and then they will die and [theoretically] won’t have used it all because of having fewer years. 151
Issue: windfall to estate? 151
Basically, the unused portion will increase the estate and mean that the heirs will get a larger inheritance than they otherwise would have. 151
Note: living expense deduction for lost years [Tonneguzzo, 1994 SCC] 151
Lost Years 151
In Andrews and Tonneguzzo, courts deducted 50% from the lost years 151
Because they won’t actually live to the age they would have, deduct for the lost years for the windfall to the estate typically 50% 151
Step 3: Factor in Contingencies: 151
Positive and negative impacts on awards 151
Statistical contingencies: affect everyone 151
∆s and πs will bring evidence about general contingencies that would have impacted π’s work years/income etc. 151
Individualized contingencies: lost chances [see e.g. Conklin v. Smith, 1978 SCC] 151
Can be positive or negative in Conklin, the π was working toward a higher-paying career, so the court awarded more on the change that he might have made a career change. 151
Caution: avoid double discounts and resist over-estimates 151
Double Discounts: see e.g. Andrews 151
Court estimated his working life at 65, but CP pension would have kicked in at 55, so they set that as the limit. 151
Then, they deducted 20% from the award for the chance, among other things, of early retirement. 151
Factored in a possible unemployment period as well. 151
Advice: don’t accept a 20% contingency deduction, because it’s probably too high – even though that happens all the time. Bring statistical evidence to bear, because actuaries have info on everything. 151
Step 4; Account for Residual Earnings 151
Consider the difference between pre-accident earning capacity and post-accident residual earning capacity [see e.g. McCabe] 151
Earnings are only going to be reduced to zero in catastrophic cases in most cases, though, π may earn less or will be unable to work full-time. 151
Step 5: Deduct for Any Overlap with Cost of Care 151
You would already have spent money on food etc., so if the cost of care calculation includes that sort of expenses (i.e. in a nursing home), deduct for this. 151
Deduct fully over the course of the prior life expectancy 151
Step 6: Factor in Collateral Benefits 152
Other sources of income replacement 152
E.g. employer wage continuation, sick benefits, disability insurance 152
Step 7: Discount to Present Value 152
See above subtract inflation rate from interest rate and apply that percentage to discount the value. 152
S. 56 of Law and Equity Act 152
Note: Issue of Taxation 152
In calculating lost earning capacity, we generally don’t take taxation into account. 152
i.e. courts calculate lost earnings on a pre-tax basis, even though awards are not taxed. 152
So, in Andrews, π was awarded based on loss of $1000/month, even though he would really only have taken home $800/month after tax if he hadn’t been injured. 152
Windfall? 152
Theoretical Justification 152
It’s a capital asset …this seems wrong. 152
Idea: the award is a valuation of the person’s earning capacity, not their actual lost earnings. 152
Basically, the court says you’re valuing the earning capacity as an asset. 152
But… no we’re not. 152
Practical Justification 152
Buffers errors 152
The calculation is complicated 152
Difference may be partly offset by tax on income from award 152
Income from award is subject to the usual rules of taxation. 152
So, maybe that justifies it. We just ignore it on both sides and pretend it’s a wash. 152
It’s not really equal, but it may be close enough that it’s not worth the effort to adjust the system. 152
Past Loss 152
See Insurance (Vehicle) Act, s. 98: 152
Despite any other enactment or rule of law but subject to this Part, a person who suffers a loss of income as a result of an accident or, if deceased, his or her personal representative, is entitled to recover from designated defendants, as damages for the income loss suffered after the accident and before the first day of trial of any action brought in relation to it, not more than the net income loss that the person suffered in that period as a result of the accident. 152
Past income loss is replaced on a post-tax basis, per s. 98. 153
Basically, we know what the take-home pay is, so we replace that. 153
Compensating Future Losses of Children & πs who did Unpaid Work 153
Where π has work history [e.g. Andrews], can use direct evidence. 153
Use current wage as a baseline 153
Consider educational and motivational track record 153
Consider evidence re life plans as basis for adjustments and contingencies 153
Children and unwaged work: lack of individualized evidence causes problems of calculation. 153
Conventional sums vs. individualized awards: 153
Teno, Fenn and Penso: $6000 awarded in each case as a rough estimate of annual earning capacity. 153
Courts have shifted from Teno model to statistical methods assessment 153
Issues of Fairness 153
What are the key indicators of success? Can we agree on these? 153
E.g. height; birth order; parental education attainment, socio-economic status, and ethnic origin 153
But, is it really fair to replicate the outcomes of an unfair world? Is it worth court time to do this? 153
Response: the tort system isn’t there to fix the world; it’s just there to replicate it The whole compensation model is based on replicating what the outcomes would have been, but for the tort. 153
Male/female: if you compare prospects of 4 year old boy and 4 year old girl, you get a disparity of about 25% 153
The tort system is just perpetuating these inequalities. 153
Gender factors in damages assessments 153
Gender neutral statistics 153
Addressing these Issues: 154
It’s becoming common for courts to adjust upwards for female πs, for two reasons: 154
Enhance past statistics with the contingency of future improvement 154
The situation is improving, especially in relation to inequality of wages. 154
Share with your friends: |