Basic Process for Assessing Damages: 97 Select  interest that deserves vindication 97 a. Restitution 97



Download 1.08 Mb.
Page9/27
Date31.01.2017
Size1.08 Mb.
#13160
1   ...   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   ...   27

Restitutionary Remedies

Basics


Restitution is both a remedy and a basis of liability.

Remedy: conceptualizing award to  based on wrongly-acquired benefit by ∆

Restitution as a remedy can be ordered either in monetary form (damages, accounting), or through another type of court order (proprietary remedies, e.g. tracing, constructive trusts)

Remedial Advantages:


Focus on ∆ benefit as opposed to  loss. Can be very useful from an evidentiary perspective:

Overcomes problems of proof  e.g. where  can establish ∆ benefit but loss is speculative; onus on ∆ to show expenses to deduct from total benefit

Strategically, ∆ gain may be larger amount than  loss [Whitwham,6 Strand Electric,7 Blake8]

May provide in rem relief (as opposed to in personam)  in rem may give  priority over other creditors, or a claim to specific property-security

But see Philips v. Homfray9

May provide some procedural advantages

E.g. limitation periods – may expire for ordinary tort, but different for K.

Established Categories of Restitution Remedy:


Money/services paid by mistake (to ∆ or to 3rd party)

Waiver of tort (for trespass, conversion, etc.) [Whitwham, Strand]

Where ∆ derived a benefit from committing a tort, but hasn’t really caused  loss,  can “waive the tort” and sue as if they were partners.

Basically, asking court to treat it as a contract case, where  and ∆ were partners in an enterprise, and an implied term was that  would get the benefit - otherwise why would  have “approved” the act? (They didn’t, really, but that’s the waiver of tort)

It’s a fiction, used to give a higher level of award without actually changing the law.

This whole fiction has now been abolished, and courts just accept that sometimes there is a restitutionary remedy for torts.

Gains from intentional torts (sometimes disguised as punitive damages?) [Whitwham; Broome v. Cassell]10

Requirements [per Broome v. Cassell]

1. Knowledge that it’s against the law

2. Conscious choice to continue because the prospects of advantage outweigh the prospects of loss/penalty

Gains from crime [Garland;11 Blake]

Breach of fiduciary duty

Intellectual property – patents, copyright

Breach of confidence [Peter Pan;12 Seager v. Copydex;13 Lac Minerals14]

If courts were confined to compensatory (expectation) damages, would be encouraging breach of K by creating an incentive to try, since the worst that would happen is you’d have to keep the original bargain.

Courts want to encourage bargaining in good faith.

Courts are comfortable with restitutionary remedy where there was a special relationship of confidence – not just any breach of K case will merit these.

Necessitous intervention

To get compensation for benefits conferred in an emergency – i.e. if there had been time, ∆ would have agreed to pay  for the service of saving their life/property

Service per quantum meruit (spousal cases)

Total failure of consideration

Void/voidable Ks (fraud, unconscionability, mistake, frustration)

Advance payments/benefits under Ks that fail to materialize

Benefits conferred under an unenforceable K [Degleman (1954, SCC)]

Domestic property  constructive trust cases [Becker v. Pettkus]15

Breach of K? Maybe.


Requirements for Restitution to be Granted


[per Garland]

1. ∆ must have acquired a benefit

The benefit can be positive (property, money, services) or negative (i.e. savings of some kind)

Does not have to be pecuniary, but must be quantifiable in monetary terms.

Onus on  to prove this component.

2. Detriment to  (causal connection)

Onus on  to prove.

3. Must be an absence of a juristic reason for the benefit (i.e. it must be unjust)

Most common juristic reasons: gifts, Ks.

Also, where required by operation of law.

Onus on  to prove

4. Other reasons to deny recovery

Onus on ∆ to prove this, once has established benefit, detriment and absence of juristic reason.

Possible reasons:

Public policy

Reasonable expectations [see e.g. Garland]

Would it be unduly oppressive/surprising for ∆ to have to pay back?

5. Defences

must prove

e.g. change of position; delay; estoppel; acquiescence

6. Choice of Remedy

Money


Constructive trust

7. Quantification


Restitution in Contract


Can restitution be a remedy for breach of K? General rule is no, so far.

Competing policies: efficient breach vs. unjust enrichment

Efficient breach theory: generally,  is entitled to compensation for loss, but ≠ for ∆ savings/benefits. [See Bank of America v. Mutual Trust (2002, SCC)]16

But restitutionary motives are often at work in defining “compensation” [recall Groves]

Increasingly, in a narrow class of cases, restitution has been made an explicit contractual remedy [Wrotham Park;17 Blake]

Limitation: it’s not a general remedy  must be a special case for disgorgement

(a) as a substitute for equitable relief?

(b) as required by public policy?

So, basically, it’s a high threshold to get restitution.

Note: Wrotham Park is still considered a leading case, but it’s not certain. [see e.g. Surrey Council v. Bredero;18 Jaggard v. Sawyer]19

Where a wrong has resulted in benefit for ∆ at  expense, courts conceptualize the transaction as ∆ having avoided a bargain with .

Quantum  Various Approaches


Compensatory:

1. Reasonable wayleave, rent [see e.g. Whitwham; Strand Electric; Wrotham Park]

Where the wrong consists of use of  property, court measures unjust enrichment by the amount ∆ should have paid had they bargained for the use in advance.

2. Opportunity costs

3. Royalty (capitalized) [see e.g. Seager]

Note: really, all three of the above categories are about opportunity costs, and are compensatory in nature. Courts just start the quantification by looking at ∆ benefit.

Accounting/Disgorgement:

4. Full value of wrongly acquired benefit (through constructive trust) [Lac Minerals]

5. Full gross revenue [see e.g. Blake]

Note, though, that courts will often apply a net revenue figure, recognizing that benefit to ∆ ≠ full amount received, but the full amount less expended $/effort.

But in Blake there was some serious moral outrage going on, and that impacts the remedy.

6. Account for full net profit [see e.g. Peter Pan; Lever v. Godwin; Phillips v. Homfray]

∆ has taken a benefit from .

7. Apportionment [argued unsuccessfully in Peter Pan; see Edwards v. Lees]20

Punitive:

8. Punitive damages based on comparative profit/savings [see e.g. Townsview;21 Broome v. Cassell]

Quantum Meruit Awards:

9. Quantum meruit based on market value (e.g. value received measure often applied in domestic cases

Often where contribution from one side is non-monetary (i.e. one spouse/cohabitant bringing in salary, the other providing childcare or other work in the home)

Assess on quantum meruit basis and impose a constructive trust over the amount.

Labour cost of cooking, cleaning, childcare, but also mgmt aspect. How would the work be priced in the marketplace?

10. Quantum meruit based on joint enterprise (e.g. value survived in domestic cases)

In this measure, we don’t get too bogged down in the specific contributions.

Ongoing contributions into joint property, assess on the current value (hence “value survived”), and then impose a constructive trust on that current value.




Download 1.08 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   ...   27




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page