Note: In chapter 2 and 3, I have used the original pagination of Innes, and excluded the new pagination of Wray


SOVEREIGN MONETARY SPACE IN ENGLAND



Download 1.48 Mb.
Page46/58
Date31.03.2018
Size1.48 Mb.
#44788
1   ...   42   43   44   45   46   47   48   49   ...   58

SOVEREIGN MONETARY SPACE IN ENGLAND

The temptations of increased seigniorage by means of debasement had proved too much for Henry VIII in the search to finance his costly wars.


205

During the 'Great Debasement' (1544-51) the silver content of the coinage was systematically reduced from 93 per cent to 33 per cent which resulted in a seigniorage to the crown amounting to over £1.2 million (Goldsmith 1987: p. 178; Davies 1996: p. 203). The exact nature of narrowly economic effects is unclear; and, in particular, the question of the relationship between metallic content of coins and prices is disputed (Innes 1913, 1914; Braudel 1984: pp. 356-59; Davies 1996). However, these considerations aside, the debasement did discredit the monarchy, created confusion and insecurity, and, like all serious monetary disorder, threatened social disintegration.

Elizabeth I's reforms stabilised a coinage that together with the successful prohibition of foreign coins was now coextensive with the state jurisdiction. Despite the involvement of Elizabeth's advisor, Sir Thomas Gresham, in the Antwerp money markets, and the existence of domestic networks of mercantile credit, the English monetary policy was unequivocally monarchical and bullionist (Munro 1979). Citing the 'abuses of merchants and brokers upon bargains of exchange', Elizabeth's minister, Lord Burghley, forbade bills of exchange transactions that were not licensed and the issue of bills by unknown merchants; and placed a l/2d in the pound (£) tax on cambium and recambium.

Other elements of state building aided the creation of monetary sovereignty. It was precisely at this time that England became a more coherent linguistic and cultural unit in which class and state were integrated by the overarching 'nation' (Mann 1986: p. 462). Significantly, 'nation' began to lose its mediaeval meaning of a group united by common kinship - as in the banking 'nations' centred on the great fifteenth- and sixteenth-century Italian families. The emerging English nation state became the basis for the impersonal trust that eventually enabled the forms of credit money to become established outside the interpersonal banking and exchange networks in which, hitherto, they had been contained.

At this juncture, however, the late sixteenth-century English state had, in effect, established a form of money that was structurally the same in all important aspects to that which had disintegrated in Rome over a thousand years earlier. At the very moment that the knowledge of the new forms of credit money was being disseminated across Europe by trade and treatise, the strongest states were reconstructing the ancient form as both symbol and measure of their sovereignty. As in the Roman system, there was a degree of separation of the forms and functions of money in Elizabethan England. The integrated money of account and silver standard coin was the accepted means of payment or settlement.
206

However, the smallest l/2d coin was the value of an hour's wage labour and, therefore, too large for petty transactions. These were conducted, as in Rome, by base metal media of exchange issued by cities and private agencies (Goldsmith 1987: p. 179). Again like Rome, gold coins were used as stores of value.

However, in the absence of further events and conditions, this development could just as readily have been inhibited by a strengthened monarchical monetary sovereignty - as it had been in France, for example. A century later, the successful foundation of the Bank of England and a form of state credit money was the result of a political struggle between the supporters of the two different forms of money -coin and credit. This outcome consisted in a remarkable coalescence of the interests of commerce and statecraft that was produced by a compromise that expressed the delicate balance between too much and too little royal power.26

On the one hand, English kings continued to assert mediaeval royal monetary prerogatives. Charles I appointed a Royal Exchanger with exclusive powers over the exchange of money and precious metals; and in 1661 Charles II sought to enforce the old statutes of Edward III and Richard II licensing bills of exchange (Munro 1979: p. 212). On the other hand, an increasing number of the same mercantile supporters of monetary stability also advocated 'Dutch finance' - that is, the creation and monetisation of a national debt.27 Over a hundred schemes for a public bank were put forward in the second half of the seventeenth century with the aim of regularising state revenue and further removing it from the arbitrary control of a monarchy with absolutist pretensions (Horsefield 1960). Many were based on Amsterdam's Wisselbank (1609) which itself had been patterned closely on Venice's Banco di Rialto (1587) (Goldsmith 1987: p. 214). As I have emphasised the techniques were by now well understood.28

The most important question of the day concerned the material base for the prospective banks' issue of credit money - that is, for its actual capacity to honour its promises to pay. Lessons had been learnt from the earlier experiments. The circulation of mere promises in the form of deposits and stock held by the mercantile and affluent classes had proved too unstable in Venice, and were viewed with suspicion. Furthermore, the Dutch had more recently experienced similar crises.29 Consequently, the authors of many schemes agreed with Defoe that 'land is the best bottom for banks' (quoted in Davies 1996: p. 260).

But, it was beginning to be realised in some quarters that promises to pay were, indeed, new forms of money sui generis in that they were not


207

actually representative of any material source of value. A 'credit theory of money' was emerging.


[0]f all beings that have existence in the minds of men, nothing is more fantastical and nice than Credit; it is never to be forced; it hangs upon opinion, it depends upon our passions of hope and fear; it comes many times unsought for, and often goes away without reason, and when once lost, is hardly to be quite recovered .. . [And] no trading nation ever did subsist and carry on its business by real stock; ... trust and confidence in each other are as necessary to link and hold people together, as obedience, love friendship, or the intercourse of speech (Charles Davenant circa 1682, quoted in Pocock 1975).
But, however 'fantastical' it might be, this trust could be cultivated for 'it very much resembles, and, in many instances, is near akin to that fame and reputation which men obtain by wisdom in governing state affairs, or by valour and conduct in the field' (Charles Davenant circa 1682, quoted in Pocock 1975: p. 77; see also Sherman 1997). There is evidence to suggest that, during the seventeenth century, a 'civic morality of trust' that could sustain this credit money economy had emerged in England, outside and beyond the relatively closed networks of the metropolitan mercantile and political elite. A culture of credit based upon the 'currency of reputation' was constructed in the wake of the collapse of an enormous expansion of personal credit relations, in the sense of deferred payment, which had occurred in the late sixteenth century (Muldrew 1998).30 During the 1570s, bilateral credit typically based on traditional oral contracts before witnesses became commonplace for a wide range of sales and services. However, for reasons that have not been explained fully, defaults soon became widespread.

Given the interconnectedness of the bilateral credit relations, defaults had extensive ramifications: total litigation in the 1580s 'might have been as high as 1,102,367 cases per year or over one suit for every household in the country' (Muldrew 1998: p. 236). It is possible, but by no means clear, that such a large-scale use of the law led to the final collapse of the personal ties of affiliation and dependence of the Middle Ages. In their wake, one might say that a process of normative reconstruction took place, in which trustworthiness came to be stressed as the paramount communal virtue rather than a personal commitment. Just as trust in God was stressed as the central religious duty, it entailed ' . . . a sort of competitive piety in which virtue of a household gave it credit . . . (Muldrew 1998: p. 195). In other words, the moral basis of a trustworthiness, which could support extensive market relations and a credit money economy, could not be taken for granted as the result of a natural sociability - or, in Innes's terms, a 'primitive law of commerce'.


208

Rather, it had to be created not only by legal enactment and enforcement; but also through culture - drama, ballads and poetry; and education (Muldrew 1998). This was the creation of a sense of impersonal or universalistic trustworthiness that people could claim by acting in a reputable manner, and not simply an obligation to honour agreements based on personal or particularistic ties of family or kin.31





Download 1.48 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   42   43   44   45   46   47   48   49   ...   58




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page