CORRUPTION IS A MAJOR HINDRANCE TO DEVELOPMENT
Larry Diamond, Senior Fellow Hoover Institute, In Search of Democracy, 2016, p. 388-9
Countries that have failed to realize their development potential in the past half century have invariably suffered yawning deficits of good governance. Why is bad governance such a pervasive and profound obstacle to development? Just as good governance promotes the accumulation of financial, physical, social, and political capital, bad governance inhibits or drains away that accumulation.
Consider the archetypical badly governed country. Corruption is endemic throughout the system of government at every level. Public infrastructure decays or is never built because the resources for it are diverted to private ends. Decisions on public expenditures are tilted toward unproductive investments—sophisticated weapons, white-elephant construction projects—that can deliver large kickbacks to the civilian officials and military officials who ward them. Schools are not built or maintained, clinics are not stocked and staffed, and roads are not repaired because the funds are squandered or stolen. Businesses cannot get licenses to operate and small producers cannot get title to their land because it would take half a year and a small fortune to navigate the shoals of a bloated, corrupt state bureaucracy. Every interaction with the state—to obtain a building permit, register a marriage or a death, report a crime, or receive a vaccination—exacts its petty, unofficial price.
In such a context of rotten governance, individuals seek governmental positions in order to collect rents and accumulate personal wealth—to convert public resources into private goods. Governmental decisions and transactions are deliberately opaque in order to hide their corrupt nature, but exposure to corrupt deeds typically brings little more than embarrassment because the rule of law does not function to constrain or punish the behavior or public officials. Power is heavily centralized and institutions of scrutiny and accountability function only on paper, or episodically, to punish the more marginal miscreants or the rivals of the truly powerful. Corruption is also rife at the bottom of the governance system because that is the climate that is set at the top, and because government workers cannot live on the salaries they are paid.
Institutions of political participation may or may not exist in this venal environment, but if they do, the government is not responsive to them. Instead, political participation cleaves society vertically, typically along ethnic lines, into competing chains of patron-client relations that all mobilize for one purpose: to get control of public resources so that they can convert them into private goods. In such a society, violent conflict is also rife, or never far from the surface, because ordinary people are exploited and desperate, rights are routinely abused, and communities are mutually resentful of any perceived advantage of the other in a zero-sum game. The only way to generate truly sustainable development in this context is to bring about a fundamental transformation in the nature and quality of governance. Granted, the ways people think and behave must change. But individual behavior is not the largest or quickest point of leverage. Such changes can only be effective if the social environment of incentives and expectations is transformed. That in turn requires a shift toward more responsible, professional, open, and accountable governance. In particular, it requires specific and well-functioning institutions of democracy, horizontal accountability, and the rule of law.
CORRUPTION UNDERMINES ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL DEVELOPMENT
Phil Williams, Rand, 2003, Faultlines of Conflict in Central Asia and the South Caucasus, ed. Olga Oliker & Thomas Szayna, [http://192.5.14.110/pubs/monograph_reports/MR1598/MR1598.ch4.pdf], p. 92
The negative consequences of corruption and rent seeking include a reduction in state building capacity, increased gaps between elites and publics, a loss of faith in government and the free market economy, the radicalization of political opposition, and the alienation of youth groups and political activists. In the short term, rent seeking helps to maintain authoritarian regimes in power; in the longer term it can contribute to their collapse. This is not surprising: corruption and rent seeking can have a profoundly alienating impact on the populace—especially when the corruption benefits are concentrated rather than diffused more broadly to ensure a higher degree of support. Another adverse consequence of corruption and rent seeking is an inhibition on foreign investment—something that is crucial to the success of transitional economies because of the deficits in indigenous capacity to finance new ventures. In view of all these negative effects, the overall, long-term impact of corruption and rent seeking is the creation of profound domestic instabilities that can all too easily feed into regime collapse, revolution, or civil war.
CORRUPTION HURTS GROWTH BY DETERRING INVESTMENT
Paulo Mauro, IMF Economist, 1995, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 3, August, p. 683
I find that corruption lowers private investment, thereby reducing economic growth, even in subsamples of countries in which bureaucratic regulations are very cumbersome. The negative association between corruption and investment, as well as growth, is significant, both in a statistical and in an economic sense. For example, if Bangladesh were to improve the integrity and efficiency of its bureaucracy to the level of that of Uruguay (this corresponds to a one-standard-deviation increase in the bureaucratic efficiency index introduced in the next section), its investment rate would rise by almost five percentage points, and its yearly GDP growth rate would rise by over half a percentage point. The magnitude of the estimated effects is even larger when instrumental variables are used.
Share with your friends: |