Chapter 5 Market Power Does It Help or Hurt the Economy? What's in This Chapter and Why



Download 113.13 Kb.
Date20.05.2018
Size113.13 Kb.
#50381

Chapter 5 Market Power

Does It Help or Hurt the Economy?

What's in This Chapter and Why

This chapter continues the development of the function of competitive markets by showing that a competitive market results in economic efficiency. Thus, the analysis of the price system and the analysis of demand and supply in previous chapters, along with the efficiency analysis contained in Chapter 3 and this chapter provide an introduction to the workings of a competitive market economy.

Chapter 6 and Chapters 7 through 9 are used to consider market failure. The monopoly and market power analysis of this chapter shows one way that markets can result in inefficiency.

The issue raised in the chapter is market power in the U.S. economy. How important is it? It is shown that if market power exists in the U.S. economy, it exists mostly in oligopolies. How do oligopolies achieve monopoly-like results? They may do so, if they can act as if they are in a cartel. The OPEC cartel is discussed because of its intrinsic interest and because it shows conditions necessary for a cartel to be successful.

If government is antagonistic to cartels or collusion--as it is in the United States—it is concluded that competitive pressures will be intense in a large economy.

Instructional Objectives

After completing this chapter, your students should know:

1. The basic monopoly analysis, including a comparison of monopoly equilibrium with competitive equilibrium.

2. Elementary conclusions about competition and economic efficiency.

3. The sources and extent of monopoly in the U.S. economy.

4. The conditions under which a cartel might succeed and be able to discuss OPEC's history in light of cartel analysis.

5. The relationship between market power and economic growth.

Key Terms

These terms are introduced in this chapter:



Market power

Monopoly


Oligopoly

Cartel


Marginal revenue

Marginal principle

Efficient output

Barrier to entry

Natural monopoly




Suggestions for Teaching

The approach taken to demand and supply analysis in Chapter 2 makes the discussion of efficiency easier for students. Depending upon your objectives for the course, you can either emphasize the formal monopoly analysis or you can use intuition to argue that a monopoly will charge a higher price and restrict output. Students are intrigued by the discussion of oligopoly and cartel behavior. The incentives to cooperate and the incentives to cheat can be developed in ways that students relate to. For instance, do students have incentives to "hold back" in classes in which grades are determined on a curve? If so, do students in fact "hold back"?

Students and automobiles are often strong complements. Both the text and boxed discussions of the automobile industry should interest and motivate students.

It is interesting to discuss with students the rationale for and the effect of the licensing of taxis, barbers, and the like. Then, the question of the licensing of physicians or child ­care centers might be raised.



Additional References

In addition to the references in the text, instructors may wish to read or assign one or more of the following:

1. "A Survey of the Car Industry," The Economist (October 17, 1992).

2. Walter Adams, "Public Policy in a Free Enterprise Economy," Chapter 13 in Walter Adams, ed., The Structure of American Industry, 8th ed. (New York: Macmillan, 1990), pp. 349‑376.

3. John Kenneth Galbraith, American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1952).

4. Steven Martin, "The Petroleum Industry," Chapter 2 in Walter Adams, ed., The Structure of American Industry, 9th ed. (New York: Macmillan, 1994).

5. F. M. Scherer and David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd ed. (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1990).

6. "The Fall of Big Business" and "Japanese Cars at Day," The Economist (April 17, 1993), pp. 13-14 and 61-62.



7. Mine K. Yucel and Carol Dahl, "Reducing U.S. Oil‑Import Dependence: A Tariff, Subsidy, or Gasoline Tax?" Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review (May 1990), pp. 17‑25.

Outline

I. GENERAL COMMENTS AND DEFINITIONS

A. Market Power

1. Firms have market power when the following conditions exist.

a. Firms can influence price in attempts to increase profits.

b. The existence of profits does not attract new firms into the industry.

2. The following conditions are required for market power.

a. A few firms control the product.

b. There are limitations on the entry of new firms.

B. Monopoly

1. A monopoly is a single seller of a product with no close substitutes.

C. Oligopoly

1. An oligopoly is a market with a few producers or sellers of a good.

D. Cartel

1. A cartel is an organized group of firms who manage output and pricing as if they were a monopoly.

II. MONOPOLY ANALYSIS

A. Demand

1. Because the monopolist is a single seller, it faces the market demand curve for the product produced.

a. This demand curve is negatively sloped and shows that the monopolist can sell more output only by lowering the price of the product.

1. This means that the output the monopolist chooses to sell affects price.

B. Marginal Revenue

1. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue associated with selling one more unit of output.

a. It is the private benefit to the monopolist of selling one more unit.

2. For a monopolist, marginal revenue is less than price.

a. Because the monopolist must lower the price on all units in order to sell additional units, marginal revenue is less than price.

b. Because marginal revenue is less than price, the marginal revenue curve will lie below the demand curve.

1. Because demand represents marginal social benefit and marginal revenue represents marginal private benefit, marginal social benefit is greater than industry marginal private benefit in monopoly.

C. The Marginal Principle

1. In choosing the output to produce, the monopolist follows the marginal principle.

a. This principle states the profit maximizing output is that output where marginal revenue equals marginal cost.

1. If marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost, the monopolist should
increase output.
2. If marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, the monopolist should decrease output.

D. Monopoly and Competition Compared

1. Unlike a competitive industry, a monopoly does not produce the efficient output. Monopolists charge a higher price and produce less output than a competitive industry.

a. Efficient output occurs where marginal social cost and marginal social benefit are equal.

b. Inefficiency occurs because of the divergence between marginal social benefit and marginal social cost.

1. At the output produced by the monopolist, marginal social benefit exceeds marginal social cost.
a. The value to consumers of an additional unit exceeds the value of the units of other goods given up to produce the additional unit - the opportunity cost.

III. MARKET POWER AND ECONOMIC EFFICIENCY

A. The Trend in Market Power

1. Some studies indicate that the U.S. economy is becoming more competitive.

a. Increased competition from imports in the manufacturing sector has decreased market power.

b. Government deregulation of the economy has decreased market power.

c. Federal government policies making mergers and price fixing more difficult have decreased market power.

d. The information revolution has increased competition in many industries, resulting in a decrease in market power.

B. Barriers to Entry

1. There are four major sources of market power in the United States.

a. Technical conditions can create entry barriers.

1. Technical conditions might be such that a technically efficient firm will supply all of a good that consumers wish to purchase at the going price.
a. Monopolies created by these technical conditions are sometimes referred to as natural monopolies.

b. Access to the supply of a product or an essential input for a product can create a barrier to entry.

c. Existing firms may develop and maintain market power through product differentiation.

d. Monopolies may be created by government regulations.

IV. OPEC: A FEW SELLERS ACTING LIKE A MONOPOLY

A. Cartel Formation

1. Three variables are important in determining the success of forming and maintaining a cartel.

a. The cartel must reach an agreement that all producers will abide by.

1. This agreement stipulates the total output to be produced by the cartel and the division of production among the members.

b. The cartel must continue to cooperate and come to new agreements as conditions change.

c. The agreement must be enforced.

1. Because it is very profitable for cartel members to cheat on the original agreement, there must be some method of enforcement.

B. The Determinants of Cartel Success

1. The fewer the number of firms and the more similar they are, the easier it is to form and operate a cartel.

a. As the number of firms increases, it becomes more difficult to include all the firms in the industry.

b. As the number of firms increases, it becomes more difficult to detect cheating on the agreement.

2. If firms are not similar, it becomes more difficult to determine the division of output and profits.

C. Problems of the OPEC Cartel

1. There are three factors accounting for the serious problems encountered by the OPEC cartel.

a. There are many members, as well as several nonmember petroleum producers.

1. The existence of large profits attracted entry to the industry and drove the price of petroleum down.

b. The members are dissimilar in that they have different and conflicting goals.

1. Countries with small reserves relative to population want higher prices now, while countries with relatively large reserves are more concerned with long‑run profits.

c. The demand for petroleum is more elastic in the long run.

1. Over time consumers have made adjustments to the higher OPEC price.

V. MARKET POWER AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

A. Basis of Economic Growth

1. Knowledge and the creation of new knowledge are the basis for much economic growth and for the growth of many firms.

2. Knowledge-based firms have several feature that lead to a monopoly or near-monopoly of their products.

a. The development of the product involves huge start-up costs.

b. There are large up-front costs involved in producing the product that has been developed.

3. Government grants monopolies of new products through copyrights and patents so that firms can cover the start-up and up-front costs of developing a product.

a. Microsoft’s first disk of Windows probably cost $50 million. Subsequent disks cost $3.

VI. GOVERNMENT AND MARKET POWER

A. Antitrust Laws

1. Antitrust laws prohibit price fixing and other types of explicit cartel or monopoly behavior.

2. Antitrust laws prohibit mergers in certain instances.

a. A merger is a combination of two or more firms into one firm.

3. Through the use of antitrust laws, government discourages market power.

4. Antitrust laws should not necessarily be used to restructure all firms with market power.

a. If the industry is a natural monopoly, monopoly profit may provide incentives for innovations that, over time, would reduce or eliminate market power.

b. The existence of monopoly profits provides an incentive for economic rent seeking.

c. The existence of profits encourages new firms to come into the industry causing prices to be lowered.


Answers to Review Questions

1. Why does the efficient output occur where marginal benefit equals marginal cost? Analyze in detail.

Efficient output occurs when the value of one more unit of a good equals its cost, where marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost. Observe the following graph, which represents the market for computers.



Suppose that the firm is considering producing an additional computer which will expand output to Q1. At Q1, the demand price is $2,000, while the supply price is only $800. If the computer is produced, consumers of computers will gain $2,000 in benefits. In order to produce the computer, society will have to sacrifice $800 worth of other goods and services. It would be possible for those who gain the $2,000 of benefits to reimburse those who lose the $800 of benefits and still be better off. This would result in a net gain of benefits equal to $1,200 ($2,000 ‑ $800).

Now suppose the firm is considering producing an additional computer which will expand output to Q2. At Q2, the supply price is $2,000, while the demand price is only $800. If an additional computer is produced there will be a net loss to society of $1,200. This loss implies that resources should be allocated away from computer production. By cutting back on computer output and increasing output in other industries, consumers of computers will lose $800 worth of benefits while others in society will gain $2,000 worth of benefits. Consumers of other goods could reimburse consumers of computers for their loss in benefits and still be better off. Net benefits, and hence efficiency, will increase. At any point where the supply price is greater than the demand price, net benefit can be increased by reallocating resources away from this industry. Such a point is inefficient.

Suppose output is at Q3 where the demand price and supply price are equal. If production were increased, the supply price would exceed the demand price. There is no way to compensate consumers of other goods for the benefits they would forego as resources are allocated to the production of computers. Likewise if production were decreased, the demand price would exceed the supply price. There is no way to compensate consumers of computers for the benefits they would forego as resources are allocated to the production of other goods and services. In both cases, one group in society will benefit and another will be made worse off. Only at the point where the demand price and the supply price are equal will net benefits be maximized and efficiency obtained. Because the demand price equals marginal benefit and the supply price equals marginal cost, equality of the demand and supply prices implies that marginal benefit and marginal cost are equal.



2. If a firm is a pure competitor, marginal revenue and price will be equal. If the firm is a monopoly, marginal revenue will be less than price. Explain these statements.

In order to understand why a pure competitor's marginal revenue is equal to price and why a monopolist's marginal revenue is less than price, recall the following facts. A pure competitor is one of many producers of a homogenous good. She faces a horizontal demand curve. This means that she can sell all the output she wishes at the market price. She is a price taker. A monopolist, on the other hand, is the only producer of a good with no close substitutes. He, in effect, is the industry and faces a downward sloping demand curve. This means that in order to sell additional units of output he must lower the price of the product. The monopolist is a price searcher.

Why does this mean that the pure competitor's marginal revenue is the same as the market price while the monopolist's marginal revenue is less than the market price? Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue associated with a one unit change in output. For a pure competitor, each additional unit of output sold will increase total revenue by an amount equal to the market price. For example, Christie, a pure competitor, sells one hundred pieces of pizza for $2 per slice. Her total revenue is $200. If she sells one hundred one pieces of pizza her total revenue is $202. Marginal revenue is $202 less $200 or $2, and $2 is the market price of pizza. Because Christie does not have to lower price in order to sell more, marginal revenue will be equal to market price.

For a monopolist, each additional unit of output sold will increase total revenue by an amount less than the market price. For example, Dan, a monopolist, can sell one bottle of Dr. Goodbody's cure‑all for $5 per bottle. His total revenue will be $5. In order to induce customers to buy more than one bottle of the tonic, he must reduce the price. This lower price must be charged for all bottles sold. Thus, to sell two bottles of cure‑all he must lower the price to $4.00 per bottle. His total revenue will now be $8 ($4 x 2). His marginal revenue will be the change in total revenue, $8 less $5, or $3. Because Dan must lower price in order to induce customers to take a greater quantity, marginal revenue will be less than price.



3. Suppose you are given the information about a monopoly that appears in the table.

Quantity

Price

Marginal Cost

1

50

20

2

45

20

3

40

20

4

35

20

5

30

20

6

25

20

7

20

20

8

15

20

9

10

20

10

5

20

a. What is the firm's total revenue for each quantity?

b. What is the firm's marginal revenue for each quantity?

c. What quantity and price should the firm choose to maximize its profits?

d. Suppose the monopolist is currently producing five units of the good. What actions should it undertake and why?

e. Use the information above to plot the demand curve faced by the monopolist, the monopolist's marginal revenue and marginal cost curves, the profit‑maximizing level of output, and the profits earned by the firm.

a. The firm's total revenue is price times quantity sold or P x Q. Applying this formula, the total revenue associated with the first unit of output is found to be 1 x $50 or $50. Using this formula the total revenue associated with each unit of output sold can be derived. These results are exhibited in column (a) in the table below.



b. The firm's marginal revenue shows the change in total revenue that is brought about by a one unit change in output. It is (TR1 ‑ TR0)/(Q1 ‑ Q0). The marginal revenue associated with increasing production from one to two units of output would be (90 ‑ 50)/(2 ‑ 1), or $40. Applying this formula to the various levels of output results in column (b) in the table below.












(a)

(b)

Q

P

MC

TR

MR

1

$50

$20

$50




2

45

20

90

$40

3

40

20

120

30

4

35

20

140

20

5

30

20

150

10

6

25

20

150

0

7

20

20

140

‑10

8

15

20

120

‑20

9

10

20

90

‑30

10

5

20

50

‑40

c. In order to maximize profit, the firm should produce where its marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal. The firm's marginal cost of production is $20 for each unit. When the firm produces 4 units, its marginal revenue is $20. Thus, the firm should produce 4 units of output. When it produces four units, the previous table indicates that people will be willing to pay $35 per unit. Thus output of 4 and price of $35 are the profit maximizing output and price.

d. If the monopolist is producing 5 units, her marginal cost is $20 while her marginal revenue is $10. The revenue received from the sale of this unit is less than the cost of producing this unit. Production of this unit will cause profits to fall by $10 ($20 ‑ $10). In order to maximize profits, the firm should cut back on output. In this instance, as output falls, profits will rise.



e. In order to draw the monopolist's demand curve, simply plot the price and quantity combinations given in the above table. This is done in the diagram below. The marginal revenue curve is drawn by plotting the marginal revenue and quantity combinations in the table. Plotting the marginal cost and quantity combinations will give the marginal cost curve. The profit maximizing output, Q*, is found by equating marginal revenue and marginal cost at point A. Q* is found by reading down from point A to the horizontal axis. Reading up from point A to the demand curve and then across to the vertical axis gives the price the monopolist will charge, P*. Profit is equal to total revenue minus total cost. Total revenue is equal to price times quantity, or area OP*BQ*. Total cost is equal to the sum of the marginal costs. It is the area under the marginal cost curve up to Q*. Thus, total cost is given by the area OC*AQ*. Total profit, total revenue minus total cost, is given by area OP*BQ* minus area OC*AQ*, or area C*P*A.



4. "A monopolist can charge whatever price it desires for its output." Is this statement true or false? Defend your answer.

The statement is false. While it is true that the monopolist is not a price taker and does exert control over the price of output, profit maximization means she cannot charge any price she desires. In the previous question, the monopolist maximized profit by selling 4 units at a price of $35 per unit. If she were to raise the price to $45 per unit and still sell 4 units, profit would go up by $40. But at the price of $45 she can only sell 2 units. Even though she charges a higher price, her profit goes down by $10 because she sells fewer units. The law of demand puts a constraint on the price charged by a monopolist.



5. State and explain the general principle to be followed in maximizing profits.

The monopolist follows the marginal principle in maximizing profits. This principle states that the output which will maximize profits is the output at which marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal. If marginal revenue is greater than marginal cost, the monopolist should increase output. If marginal revenue is less than marginal cost, the monopolist should decrease output.



This principle is quite easy to understand. For example, suppose marginal revenue is $10 while marginal cost is $7. If the monopolist produces this unit of output, profits will increase by $3 ($10 ‑ $7). Likewise, if marginal revenue is $10 and marginal cost is $15, production of this unit of output will cause profits to fall by $5 ($10 ‑ $15). Since profits will increase whenever marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost, and profits will fall whenever marginal cost exceeds marginal revenue, they must be at a maximum when marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal. This same idea is depicted in the graph below.

D represents the monopolist's demand, MR his marginal revenue, and MC his marginal cost. We have already discussed the fact that marginal revenue lies below the demand curve because that the monopolist must lower price in order to sell more output. Suppose the monopolist is currently producing output 0Q1. At 0Q1, marginal revenue is equal to OR1 or distance AC, while marginal cost is equal to OC1 or distance AB. If output is increased by one unit, profits will rise by an amount equal to OR1 minus OC1 or distance BC. Thus, anytime the monopolist is producing at a point where marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost, it is possible to increase profits by increasing output.

Likewise, if the monopolist is producing output 0Q2, marginal revenue will be OR2 or distance EF. Marginal cost will be OC1 or distance EG. The firm is earning a loss of OR2 minus OC1 or FG on this unit of output. By decreasing output by one unit, profits will increase by FG. Thus, anytime the monopolist is producing at a point where marginal cost exceeds marginal revenue, it is possible to increase profits by decreasing output. Only where marginal cost and marginal revenue are equal (output Q3) will profits be at a maximum.

6. Use graphical analysis to compare and contrast the economic outcome of monopoly with the economic outcome of pure competition.

The following graph can be used to compare the economic outcome of monopoly with the economic outcome of pure competition.



The supply curve for the competitive industry (S) is the marginal cost curve (MC) for the monopoly. D, the demand curve, is the same for both monopoly and pure competition. Equilibrium for pure competition occurs where demand and supply intersect at point A. Output is 0Q1 and price is OB. Profits are zero (there is a normal rate of earnings).

The monopolist produces where marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal at point E. Output is 0Q2 and price is OF. Monopoly profit is equal to area BFGE. So monopoly price is higher than the competitive price and monopoly output is lower. The monopolist may earn a profit. For the competitive industry, demand price (marginal benefit for society) equals the supply price (marginal cost to society). All potential gains from trade are realized. For the monopoly, marginal revenue (marginal benefits for the monopolist) equals the supply price. Because demand price is greater than marginal revenue, demand price is greater than supply price. Marginal benefit for society exceeds marginal cost, and there are unrealized gains from trade.

7. "Because a monopolist can extract a higher price than a firm that is a pure competitor, the monopolist will always earn a profit." Is this statement true or false? Defend your answer.

This statement is false. In order to maximize profits, the monopolist must produce the quantity at which marginal revenue and marginal cost are equal. This means that the monopolist is not free to charge whatever price she desires. Instead she must charge the price that consumers are willing to pay for this profit maximizing quantity. Depending upon the monopolist's costs relative to consumer demand, it is possible that no profit will be earned. The monopolist may even earn a loss.



8. List and briefly discuss the major sources of monopoly in the United States.

There are four major sources of monopoly in the United States: technical conditions that require production to take place on a very large scale, control of the supply of a product or of essential production inputs, product differentiation, and government regulation. If technical conditions are such that a factory must produce an extremely large output in order to be technically efficient, it is possible that a single firm could provide the majority of output that consumers would want to buy. In this instance, a monopoly‑type structure would emerge. Cable television supplies an example of this situation.

Monopoly may also emerge if a single firm or a small group of firms control the only source of supply of a product or an essential input for a product. For example, the DeBeers Company controls most of the world's diamond production, and hence has a monopoly on the world diamond market.

Firms may also develop and maintain market power through product differentiation. If firms can convince consumers that their product is superior, they can raise price and make only a small sacrifice in terms of sales.

Finally, government regulations have been a source of monopoly. For example, regulations limiting the number of doctors that are able to enter the medical profession work to restrict supply and raise price. Tariffs and other types of regulation designed to limit the number of imports have the same effect on the price of the regulated goods. Thus, government actions may actually hinder competition and thereby impose a loss on society.

9. What is a cartel? What factors help to maintain a cartel? What factors encourage its dissolution?

A cartel is an organized group of producers who manage their output and pricing as if they were a monopoly. The purpose of the cartel is to restrict output and raise price above the competitive price. In order to be successful, the cartel must do two things: restrict output and restrict the entry of new firms. The major incentive holding the cartel together is the incentive to earn a profit. As long as the cartel succeeds, price will be above marginal cost and the firms may earn a monopoly profit.

While the desire for profit works to hold the cartel together, this same desire works to dissolve the cartel. As long as output is restricted, the price will be a monopoly price. Suppose a firm cheats by expanding output. It can now sell more output at the monopoly price and earn a profit even greater than the one possible under the cartel agreement. This same incentive works upon the other firms in the cartel. If all firms cheat, industry supply will increase and price will fall.

The larger the number of firms in the industry, the more difficult it will be to detect the cheater. For example, if there are only two firms in the cartel and price begins to fall, it is relatively easy to discover if the price decrease is due to a decrease in demand or due to an expansion of output by one of the firms. On the other hand, if there are fifteen firms in the cartel, it becomes much more difficult to identify the source of the price decline. With detection less easy, the cost the cheater would have to bear through cartel discipline falls and cheating becomes more prevalent.

In addition to increasing the probability of cheating, large numbers also make it difficult for firms to reach an agreement that will allow the cartel to organize. As the number of firms increases, it becomes more and more difficult to include all or at least most of the major firms in the industry. There are likely to problems of a "holdout," a firm that refuses to join the cartel, but reaps the benefits of increased profits if the cartel is formed.

Another problem with large numbers of firms is the fact that increases in numbers are generally accompanied by increases in heterogeneity. The less similar the firms, the more difficult it becomes to reach agreement. For example, suppose all firms in the group can be broken into two groups: low‑cost producers and high‑cost producers. In order to produce output at minimum cost the low‑cost producers will have to produce a greater share of industry output. These producers may feel that they deserve a greater share of industry profits. High‑cost producers, on the other hand, may argue that because they were forced to cut back on their production they should receive a share of profits greater than their output share. The possibility of these and other conflicts makes a cartel agreement very difficult to reach as the number of firms increases.



10. "Profits on drugs are too high. Drug companies should not be allowed to profit excessively from drugs necessary to treat serious diseases." Discuss this statement.

Government provides drug companies with this market power through the granting of patents. While it is true that drug companies do profit from their products, the role that this profit plays in the development of new drugs must be considered. The research undertaken by this companies is both expensive and risky. Thus, the profits that companies reap as a result of patents induces firms to bear this expense and risk. Goldberg argues that monopoly profits are necessary to get firms to undertake the research necessary to discover and develop new drugs. Without such activity, drugs to treat serious diseases would not be available. Nevertheless, as Friedman, a staunch advocate of the market, says, a situation may exist which requires government intervention to regulate an "essential" monopolized good. This is a judgement call.



11. Evaluate the following statement. "Because monopoly results in economic inefficiency and in large profits for a few powerful corporations, we should enforce regulations to break up these firms or eliminate their profits."

It is true that an effort to eliminate monopoly profits either through regulations that would increase competition or through regulations that would eliminate monopoly profit may increase economic efficiency. It is equally true that policies to eliminate such profits may have some undesirable consequences. The possibility of obtaining monopoly profits encourages economic rent seeking. Economic rent seeking means that individuals attempt to gain an economic advantage by offering improved products or by producing products at a lower cost. Eliminating monopoly profits will decrease this incentive, thereby imposing some cost on society.

In addition to lowering incentives to engage in economic rent seeking, the elimination of profits inhibits the potential threat of entry into the monopoly industry. Monopoly profits signal other producers that resources should flow into the industry. The threat of entry encourages the monopolist to charge a price less than that which would be charged in the absence of the threat. Eliminating profits reduces the incentive for resources to flow into the industry and thereby lowers the threat of entry. As a result, a monopolist may be able to extend his or her power. These arguments show that although monopoly does cause inefficiency in society, any actions designed to eliminate the monopoly must be carefully evaluated.

12. According to the box, “The Battle between American and Japanese Automobile Firms,” why were the Japanese firms successful in the battle?

Japanese firms were successful in the battle because management in the U. S. automobile industry enjoyed the “quiet life.” In 1981, wages in the automobile industry were 50 percent greater than average wages in manufacturing. In addition, management allowed production methods to become obsolete and ignored quality problems. When the energy crisis occurred in the 1970s, it caught U. S. car manufacturers off guard. Demand for imports surged. These cars were cheaper and of a higher quality than their U. S. counterparts. Japanese managers adopted quality-control, inventory, and human relations policies that resulted in productivity that exceeded U. S. manufacturers. Just-in-time manufacturing, quality circles, and continuous improvement also contributed to the productivity of Japanese firms.



13. What are the advantages and disadvantages of government choosing the industry standard for computer operating systems?

If the widespread belief that the Mac operating system is technically superior to the MS system is true, then we are now entrenched on an inefficient technological path that the market cannot reverse. The primary advantage of government choosing the industry standard for computer operating systems is that they would likely choose the system that is technically efficient. This, of course, assumes that there are government officials with the expertise to make this decision.

A disadvantage of allowing the government to set the standard for computer operating systems is that the government’s choice may not be the choice that maximizes the satisfaction of the most consumers. Despite technical inefficiencies, the public may place a greater value on MS systems.

Another disadvantage of allowing the government to choose our operating system is that this would likely stifle innovation on the part of potential competitors in this market. Microsoft achieved its dominance through economic rent-seeking. Had the government chosen the Mac as the standard for operating systems, MS would have had no economic incentive for innovation. In addition, Apple would have no incentive for innovation since they are already guaranteed dominance through the government’s protection.



14. For the sake of the question, assume that Apple’s operating systems were and are superior to the MS systems. Explain why DOS dominated the early Mac systems and why only Windows dominated later Mac systems. Given Windows’ dominant position, how could a new operating system replace Windows?

Although some argue that the early Mac operating system was technically superior to DOS, the MS DOS systems were still chosen over the Mac. Authors Liebowitz and Margolis argue that the DOS systems were superior with respect to cost. First, DOS was cheaper because it took less computing power than the Mac’s graphical interface. Second, DOS was faster. Third, Mac’s had limited hard drive capacity; therefore, users had to change floppies in order to change programs.



Even though DOS dominated this early market, users were not locked into the operating system. Users were ready to switch over to Windows when it first entered the market. Again, many argue that the Mac system was technically superior to the early Windows system, but consumers still chose Windows for economical reasons. First, Window could run DOS programs, and second, Windows maintained backward compatibility, so that upgrading was less costly. Microsoft had the better product in terms of consumer preferences and cost considerations.

15. Go to http://www.swcollege.com/bef/econ_news.html and click on monopoly under the microeconomics section. Choose an article of interest, read the full summary and answer the questions. (Some of these questions may go beyond the materials in this course. If you run into such questions you may want to try to answer anyway, go to a different article, or just answer the ones that seem appropriate.)

Choices of articles and answers will vary.

Download 113.13 Kb.

Share with your friends:




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page