Chapter 1 What Is Economics?



Download 4.38 Mb.
Page62/88
Date19.10.2016
Size4.38 Mb.
#4305
1   ...   58   59   60   61   62   63   64   65   ...   88

15.5 Welfare Effects

LEARNING OBJECTIVE


  1. Is price discrimination good or bad for society as a whole?

Is price discrimination a good thing or a bad thing? It turns out that there is no definitive answer to this question. Instead, it depends on circumstances. We illustrate this conclusion with a pair of exercises.

This exercise illustrates a much more general proposition: If a price discriminating monopolist produces less than a nondiscriminating monopolist, then price discrimination reduces welfare. This proposition has an elementary proof. Consider the price discriminating monopolist’s sales, and then allow arbitrage. The arbitrage increases the gains from trade, since every transaction has gains from trade. Arbitrage, however, leads to a common price like that charged by a nondiscriminating monopolist. Thus, the only way that price discrimination can increase welfare is if it leads a seller to sell more output than he or she would otherwise. This is possible, as the next exercise shows.

In Exercise 2, we see that price discrimination that brings in a new group of customers may increase the gains from trade. Indeed, this example involves a Pareto improvement: The seller and Group 2 are better off, and Group 1 is no worse off, than without price discrimination. (A Pareto improvement requires that no one is worse off and at least one person is better off.)

Whether price discrimination increases the gains from trade overall depends on circumstances. However, it is worth remembering that people with lower incomes tend to have more elastic demand, and thus get lower prices under price discrimination than absent price discrimination. Consequently, a ban on price discrimination tends to hurt the poor and benefit the rich, no matter what the overall effect.

A common form of price discrimination is known as two-part pricing. Two-part pricing usually involves a fixed charge and a marginal charge, and thus offers the ability for a seller to capture a portion of the consumer surplus. For example, electricity often comes with a fixed price per month and then a price per kilowatt-hour, which is two-part pricing. Similarly, long distance and cellular telephone companies charge a fixed fee per month, with a fixed number of “included” minutes, and a price per minute for additional minutes. Such contracts really involve three parts rather than two parts, but are similar in spirit.

Figure 15.2 Two-part pricing

description: http://images.flatworldknowledge.com/mcafee/mcafee-fig15_002.jpg

From the seller’s perspective, the ideal two-part price is to charge marginal cost plus a fixed charge equal to the customer’s consumer surplus, or perhaps a penny less. By setting price equal to marginal cost, the seller maximizes the gains from trade. By setting the fixed fee equal to consumer surplus, the seller captures the entire gains from trade. This is illustrated in Figure 15.2 "Two-part pricing".


KEY TAKEAWAYS


  • If a price discriminating monopolist produces less than a nondiscriminating monopolist, then price discrimination reduces welfare.

  • Price discrimination that opens a new, previously unserved market increases welfare.

  • A ban on price discrimination tends to hurt the poor and benefit the rich, no matter what the overall effect.

  • Two-part pricing involves a fixed charge and a marginal charge.

  • The ideal two-part price is to charge marginal cost plus a fixed charge equal to the customer’s consumer surplus, in which case the seller captures the entire gains from trade.

EXERCISES


  1. Let marginal cost be zero for all quantities. Suppose that there are two equal-sized groups of customers, Group 1 with demand q(p) = 12 – p, and Group 2 with demand q(p) = 8 – p. Show that a nondiscriminating monopolist charges a price of 5, and the discriminating monopolist charges Group 1 the price of 6 and Group 2 the price of 4. Then calculate the gains from trade, with discrimination and without, and show that price discrimination reduces the gains from trade.

  2. Let marginal cost be zero for all quantities. Suppose that there are two equal-sized groups of customers, Group 1 with demand q(p) = 12 – p, and Group 2 with demand q(p) = 4 – p. Show that a nondiscriminating monopolist charges a price of 6, and the discriminating monopolist charges Group 1 the price of 6 and Group 2 the price of 2. Then calculate the gains from trade, with discrimination and without, and show that price discrimination increases the gains from trade.


15.6 Natural Monopoly

LEARNING OBJECTIVES


  1. When there is a scale economy, what market prices will arise?

  2. How is the monopoly price constrained by the threat of entry?

A natural monopoly arises when a single firm can efficiently serve the entire market because average costs are lower with one firm than with two firms. An example is illustrated in Figure 15.3 "Natural monopoly". In this case, the average total cost of a single firm is lower than if two firms were to split the output between them. The monopolist would like to price at pm, which maximizes profits. [1]

Historically, the United States and other nations have regulated natural monopoly products and supplies such as electricity, telephony, and water service. An immediate problem with regulation is that the efficient price—that is, the price that maximizes the gains from trade—requires a subsidy from outside the industry. We see the need for a subsidy in Figure 15.3 "Natural monopoly" because the price that maximizes the gains from trade is p1, which sets the demand (marginal value) equal to the marginal cost. At this price, however, the average total cost exceeds the price, so that a firm with such a regulated price would lose money. There are two alternatives. The product could be subsidized: Subsidies are used with postal and passenger rail services in the United States and historically for many more products in Canada and Europe, including airlines and airplane manufacture. Alternatively, regulation could be imposed to limit the price to p2, the lowest break-even price. This is the more common strategy used in the United States.



Figure 15.3 Natural monopoly

description: http://images.flatworldknowledge.com/mcafee/mcafee-fig15_003.jpg

There are two strategies for limiting the price: price-cap regulation, which directly imposes a maximum price, and rate of return regulation, which limits the profitability of firms. Both of these approaches induce some inefficiency of production. In both cases, an increase in average cost may translate into additional profits for the firm, causing regulated firms to engage in unnecessary activities.


KEY TAKEAWAYS


  • A natural monopoly arises when a single firm can efficiently serve the entire market.

  • Historically, the United States and other nations have regulated natural monopolies including electricity, telephony, and water service.

  • The efficient price is typically unsustainable because of decreasing average cost.

  • Efficient prices can be achieved with subsidies that have been used, for example, in postal and passenger rail services in the United States and historically for several products in Canada and Europe, including airlines and airplane manufacture. Alternatively, regulation could be imposed to limit the price to average cost, the lowest break-even price. This is the more common strategy in the United States.

  • Two common strategies for limiting the price are price-cap regulation, which directly imposes a maximum price, and rate of return regulation, which limits the profitability of firms. Both of these approaches induce some inefficiency of production.




Directory: site -> textbooks
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. Preface
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. Preface Introduction and Background
textbooks -> Chapter 1 Introduction to Law
textbooks -> 1. 1 Why Launch!
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License without attribution as requested by the work’s original creator or licensee. Preface
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License
textbooks -> This text was adapted by The Saylor Foundation under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 0 License

Download 4.38 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   58   59   60   61   62   63   64   65   ...   88




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page