*Topicality/Definitions Democracy Promotion Includes Military Intervention


Corruption Good: Promotes Peace and Stability



Download 2.51 Mb.
Page62/159
Date18.10.2016
Size2.51 Mb.
#2395
1   ...   58   59   60   61   62   63   64   65   ...   159

Corruption Good: Promotes Peace and Stability



COURRPTION PLAYS A KEY ROLE IN MAINTAINING SOCIAL BONDS AND POLITICAL STABILITY

Italo Pardo, Fellow, University of Kent, 2004, Between Morality and the Law: corruption, anthropology, and comparative society, ed. I. Pardo, p. 11

Corruption at once draws and thrives on injustice, exploitation and inequality, distortions of power and betrayal of fundamental principles of citizenship, for those who do not have access to, or refuse to engage in corruption are at a disadvantage. But corruption may also help to maintain social bonds and to engender new ones. To treat corruption simply as an aberration would be inexcusably simplistic, betraying ignorance of an empirical reality that spans illegal, as well as not strictly illegal actions. To put it more clearly, although the form and in some way the nature of corruption, particularly in public life, may change in different political systems (for example, democratic, totalitarian), it must be identified for what it is; an aspect (usually highly problematic) of social and economic exchange. As Scott points out, it may be seen as a channel for political demands and ‘must be understood as a regular, repetitive, and integral part of the operation of most political systems.’ (1972, p. viii).

Thus, corruption may well be a pathology but, broadly in agreement with Gupta (1994, p. 376), it is unhelpful to treat it as a dysfunctional aspect of state organizations. For the purpose of precise analysis, it should be identified as their product, not some sort of bug that is alien to them. Degrees of corruption may be encouraged by a shortage of resources and may themselves become useful resources. As Humphrey and Sneath argue, corruption in the Post-Socialist world is explained by current economic circumstances and the degree of reform of the bureaucracy, rather than reflecting some “eastern” cultural disposition, the specific forms of corruption which they examine are the result of predatory responses by officials to the shrinking of resources available to them. Such shrinking of resources followed the breakdown of the system (see also Rigi, 1989, on political corruption in the USSR), in a political ambiance where state service jobs are still very prestigious, where those charged with enforcing state regulations will consider themselves an elite and where the ethical valuation of their work among those in state service remains high.




Corruption Good: Promotes Economic Growth


CORRUPTION INCREASES ECONOMIC GROWTH

Paulo Mauro, IMF Economist, 1995, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 3, August, p. 681-2

The debate on the effects of corruption is particularly fervent. Beginning with Leff [1964] and Huntington [1968], some authors have suggested that corruption might raise economic growth, through two types of mechanisms. First, corrupt practices such as "speed money" would enable individuals to avoid bureaucratic delay. Second, government employees who are allowed to levy bribes would work harder, especially in the case where bribes act as a piece rate. While the first mechanism would increase the likelihood that corruption be beneficial to growth only in countries where bureaucratic regulations are cumbersome, the second one would operate regardless of the level of red tape. In contrast, Shleifer and Vishny [1993] argue that corruption would tend to lower economic growth, and Rose-Ackerman [1I978] warns of the difficulty of limiting corruption to areas in which it might be economically desirable.' Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny [1991] provide evidence that countries where talented people are allocated to rent-seeking activities tend to grow more slowly.
CORRUPTION POSITIVELY ASSOCIATED WITH GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT

Mushtaq H. Khan, Department of Economics, University of London, 1998, European Journal of Development Research, June, 10 (1): 15-39, [http://mercury.soas.ac.uk/users/mk17/Docs/Corruption%20EJDR.pdf]

In contrast, Myrdal [1968] argued that the possibility of corruption may induce bureaucrats to deliberately introduce legislation which created new obstacles. Myrdal’s argument anticipated some of the rent-seeking literature to come in the seventies and eighties. Since bureaucrats can always create new possibilities of extracting bribes by creating new restrictions, Myrdal, and the rent-seeking literature generally is suspicious of any corruption. This type of argument suggests that in general corruption signals harmful rent-seeking by state officials who have deliberately created value-reducing restrictions whose effects leave society worse off. This approach too cannot do justice to the widespread evidence of substantial corruption in many developing countries which enjoyed high rates of growth. Indeed historical evidence suggests the presence of widespread corruption in the currently advanced countries at an earlier stage of their development. The gradual reduction of corruption in the successful developers may have been the result rather than the precondition of successful development.
CORRUPTION CAN BE POSITIVE

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 107-8



Notwithstanding this widespread condemnation there is a line of thought, quite evident in certain social science writings, which views corruption in nothing like so negative a light, which on the contrary maintains that at certain stages of development corruption can play a positive role. This line of thinking can be traced back at least to the critical reaction of some American journalists and political scientists to the exposes of writers like Steffens.
CORRUPTION PROMOTES ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT, INVESTMENT AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 111-2



If we subject this conception to critical scrutiny then we may be able to examine the consequences of corruption in a different light. During the first development decade of the 1960s economists and other observers became increasingly aware of the serious impediments to spontaneous growth in UDCs. Shortage of Capital, entrepreneurial talent, technical skills; structural features which could prevent such an economy from breaking out of a low-income equilibrium trap – these and other factors produced an orthodoxy which emphasized the indispensability of extensive government intervention for development. Economists, maintains Leff, “collected their problems, placed them in a box labeled ‘public policy’ and turned them over to the governments of the underdeveloped countries” (Leff, 1964, p. 9). In a situation where the state is heavily involved in the economy, links with the bureaucracy are essential for most economic activities. And it is here that graft – the illegal purchase of favors from the bureaucracy – can have beneficial effects.

Firstly, corruption can assist economic development by making possible a higher rate of investment than would otherwise have been the case. Investment decisions always involve risks but the risks are much greater in UDCs primarily because lack of data and (often arbitrary) government intervention make it extremely difficult to estimate future supply and demand. In such circumstances the existence of opportunities for graft provide some kind of guarantee that entrepreneurs will be able to continue influencing the administration despite shifts in policy. In another sense corruption acts as a form of insurance, this time against the pursuit by governments of bad policies. Where a government is proceeding energetically in the wrong direction, corruption can mitigate the losses in the sense that whilst the ‘wrong’ policy is busily implemented entrepreneurs are through graft are subverting it and promoting another. For example, an important element in Latin American inflation in the 1960s, according to Leff, was stagnation in agricultural production leading to increases in the price of food. The governments of both Chile and Brazil attempted to deal with this problem by using the administration to hold down food prices. In Chile the bureaucracy behaved correctly, enforced price controls only to exacerbate the stagnation in food production. In Brazil, by contrast, a corrupt bureaucracy allowed the controls to be undermined with the result that food producers received higher prices which in turn, stimulated agricultural production. We thus conclude that entrepreneurs together with corrupt officials produced a more effective economic policy than government.

Corruption can also promote competition and efficiency: entrepreneurs compete for scarce resources such as import licenses, foreign exchange, government contracts and the like, since payment of the highest bribe is one of the principle criteria of allocation then a premium is placed on ability to pay. Ability to pay depends upon the respective efficiency of the competing firms: therefore allocation of resources by bribery encourages efficiency and competition. Leff believes that the insinuation of this “back-door” competition is particularly important as market imperfections tend to weaken competitive pressures in many areas of underdeveloped economies.
AMERICAN HISTORY PROVES THAT CORRUPTION PROMOTES ECONOMIC GROWTH

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 114

Huntington too, in a section on corruption in his influential Political Order in Changing Societies, agrees that it can often promote economic development. During America’s ‘gilded Age” (the 1870s and 1880s) the notorious corruption of state legislatures and city authorities by business interests and those seeking franchises for public utilities is widely held to have accelerated the growth of the American economy. It may be doubted, for example, whether the necessary levels of investment needed to build America’s railways would have been forthcoming without what many considered to be the excessively generous land grants that went with the contracts (see for example, Brogan, 1987, ch. 17). Similarly during the Kubitschek era in Brazil (1954-60), according to Huntington, a high rate of economic development corresponded with an upsurge in corruption as entrepreneurs bought protection and assistance from conservative rural legislators. Huntington quotes Myron Weiner who, in relation to India, asserts that the country would be paralyzed by administrative rigidity were it not for the flexibility introduced by baksheewsh. Indeed attempts to reduce the latter in countries such as Egypt served only to produce additional obstacles to economic development.
CORRUPTION PROMOTES ECONOMIC GROWTH

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 116

Put most simply corruption is held to promote economic growth and political development. The two are of course closely interrelated: economic growth is crucial if a government is to maintain legitimacy in the face of increased mass mobilization that rapid social change produces. Corruption is believed to promote economic growth in the following ways: it assists capital formation; it fosters entrepreneurial abilities; allows business interests to penetrate the bureaucracy and, lastly permits the logic of the market to insinuate itself into transactions from which public controls attempt to exclude it.
CORRUPTION INCREASES GROWTH: INCREASES CAPITAL

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 116-7



Capital Formation Indigenous capital is scarce in UDCs for basically two reasons: the very condition of underdevelopment itself – the predominance of peasant agriculture, low cash income, limited opportunities for commercial transactions, poor communications and so on – both signifies a shortage of capital as well as serious obstacles to its accumulation. Secondly, the predominance of international capital backed by sophisticated technology and marketing techniques makes it difficult for local entrepreneurs to break into and reap adequate profits from such markets as exist. Under these circumstances the public sector offers a convenient alternative source of capital. That is to say the politician or bureaucrat may use resources he [sic] has appropriated illegally to launch himself [sic] on a business career or significantly expand one he [sic] has already started. Whether we are talking about actual funds or such things as import licenses, loans, timber, mining, or land concessions, their appropriation can play a key role in the emergence of an entrepreneurial class. In fact a number of writers have imputed to corruption a significant part in the formation of a bourgeois class in underdeveloped economies. Applied usually to the newer states of Asia and Tropical Africa, the idea is that access to public resources ma be necessary to fuel the take-off of indigenous enterprise. A study of private companies in Zambia, for example, revealed that public office had provided the main launching pad for a subsequent career in the world of business (see Szeftel, 1982; see also Crouch, 1979). There are certain parallels here in the relationship between the state and the rise of a commercial bourgeoisie in Europe from the sixteenth century onwards. Then the sale of monopolies, tax farms and other forms of privileged access to economic opportunities provided the kinds of guarantee needed by a nascent commercial class. Returning to the contemporary context this argument is obviously valid only if the accumulated capital is used inside the country in “productive” economic activities.
CORRUPTION INCREASES GROWTH: SPURS ENTREPRENEURSHIP

Robin Theobald, Senior Lecturer in Sociology, Polytechnic of Central London, 1990, Corruption, Development and Underdevelopment, p. 117-8



Entrepreneurialism Sustained economic growth clearly requires capital, but capital alone is not enough. The ability to identify markets, to develop products, to mobilize and coordinate factors of production, to adjust quickly to changing circumstances – all are equally indispensable. It is assumed that such a complex of abilities was a necessary ingredient of industrial development in Europe and that without the “entrepreneur” the industrial revolution could not have taken off. The failure of many UDCs to exhibit appropriate levels of growth, especially in their manufacturing sectors, is often attributed to the relative scarcity of entrepreneurial talent plus the traditional restraints on entrepreneurship posted by kinship obligations, norms of hospitality, ceremonial and the like. In so far as entrepreneurialism is important for economic development, then corruption may encourage the associated talents. Where corruption is normal and widespread it is likely to generate a climate of opportunism, risk-taking and profit-seeking. Indeed, recalling Merton’s argument earlier on in this chapter, from an economic point of view there is no difference between legal and illegal enterprises. Illegal enterprises require planning, forethought, ingenuity, a careful (no doubt even more careful) assessment of risks and costs, adaptability and so forth. Clearly, more mundane acts of corruption – the policeman who extracts a bribe at a checkpoint, the immigration officer who refuses to stamp your passport without “dash” –amount to little more than the unashamed abuse of public authority and require little in the way of “enterprise.” (Although it would be wrong to assume that such acts were completely devoid of an ability to estimate the market value of one’s “product” and the risks entailed. See for example Riding on Mexican traffic policemen, 1985, ch. 6.)



Download 2.51 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   58   59   60   61   62   63   64   65   ...   159




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page