Source: (CRESME, 2013)
Additionally, by aggregating the identified PPP 18 sectors into three main groups of interventions, we see an increasing emphasis on urban regeneration, meaning the set of regeneration interventions on built space, functional to improve the quality of life2. It is a market sector, triggered mainly by municipalities, which approximately represented 70% of demand and 17% of the total business volume between 2002 and 2012, and it was the only sector with a total positive balance sheet in 2012. Basic service sectors (transportation, health and education and social) and essential service sectors (water, energy, lighting, cemetery services, waste disposal) were the main sectors with reference to revenues, but during the last year these sectors registered a decline in the amounts linked to tender notices.
Compared to the size of PPPs, in 2012, works of less than 5 million euros continue to grow and investments have mainly covered initiatives of higher amount. The initiatives of less than 5 million euros were 1,553 corresponding to a total of 974 million, that are at odds respectively in number and amount, of 92% and 11% of the PPP total market when excluding the initiatives for which we do not know the value of the contract. The initiatives of more than 5 million euros, on the other hand, were just 127 (only 8% of demand) but their economic value exceeded the 7.7 billion equivalent to 89% of the total market of PPPs (in 2011 initiatives were 169 for 12.2 million euro equal to 92% of the market).
Table 1 – the macro fields of PPP: number and amount of races counted in 2002, 2005, 2008-2012 (amounts in millions of euros)
Source: www.infopieffe.it
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
2002
|
2005
|
2008
|
2009
|
2010
|
2011
|
2012
|
Total2002-2012
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Races
|
Number
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Essential services
|
115
|
207
|
297
|
372
|
860
|
662
|
911
|
4.189
|
Basic services
|
33
|
38
|
131
|
168
|
175
|
195
|
212
|
1.150
|
Urban re generation
|
188
|
745
|
894
|
1.360
|
2.037
|
1.975
|
2.081
|
11.439
|
TOTAL__853,6__223,6__142,4__68,6'>TOTAL__336__990__1.322__1.900'>TOTAL
|
336
|
990
|
1.322
|
1.900
|
3.072
|
2.832
|
3.204
|
16.778
|
|
Variation %
|
|
‘12/’02
|
‘12/’05
|
‘12/’08
|
‘12/’09
|
‘12/’10
|
‘12/’11
|
|
|
Essential services
|
692,2
|
340,1
|
206,7
|
144,9
|
5,9
|
37,6
|
|
|
Basic services
|
542,4
|
457,9
|
61,8
|
26,2
|
21,1
|
8,7
|
|
|
Urban re generation
|
1.006,9
|
179,3
|
132,8
|
53,0
|
2,2
|
5,4
|
|
|
TOTAL
|
853,6
|
223,6
|
142,4
|
68,6
|
4,3
|
13,1
|
|
|
|
Amount(Mlns euro)
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
Essential services
|
455
|
3.002
|
1.460
|
1.335
|
4.173
|
3.840
|
2.953
|
21.430
|
Basic services
|
349
|
1.764
|
3.525
|
3.162
|
4.751
|
8.277
|
4.524
|
37.627
|
Urban re generation
|
488
|
1.381
|
966
|
1.410
|
1.000
|
1.171
|
1.204
|
11.951
|
TOTAL
|
1.292
|
6.146
|
5.951
|
5.907
|
9.924
|
13.288
|
8.682
|
71.008
|
|
Variation %
|
|
‘12/’02
|
‘12/’05
|
‘12/’08
|
‘12/’09
|
‘12/’10
|
‘12/’11
|
|
|
Essential services
|
549,2
|
-1,6
|
102,3
|
121,2
|
-29,2
|
-23,1
|
|
|
Basic services
|
1.195,0
|
156,5
|
28,3
|
43,1
|
-4,8
|
-45,3
|
|
|
Urban re generation
|
147,0
|
-12,8
|
24,6
|
-14,6
|
20,4
|
2,9
|
|
|
TOTAL
|
572,1
|
41,3
|
45,9
|
47,0
|
-12,5
|
-34,7
|
|
|
THEORY-Elaboration of the reference theoretical framework
PPP, SCA and IFRIC 12: A literature survey
("Before" and "After" the application of IFRIC 12)
In some countries, infrastructure for services and public works (stadiums, kindergartens, roads, ports, airports, hospitals, cemeteries, prisons, parking lots, telecommunications networks, water distribution systems, networks for the supply of energy), is created, managed and controlled directly by the public sector taking care of the maintenance over time through direct financial allocations (Campra, 2005, 2012; Hall, 2008).
However, subsequent to the introduction of new stringent budgetary constraints, the respect of general government budgetary balances (Stability Pact in EU countries), and the increasing scarcity of resources, worsened by the financial crisis, in some countries, over the past twenty years, (Borgonovi, 2005, 2006, 2009; Amatucci, Vecchi 2009, 2011), governments have introduced (as shown in the following table), public-private partnership (PPP), through contractual service arrangements (Robinson 2001; Hawksworth, 2001), in order to attract private sector participation in the development, financing, operation and maintenance of works and utilities (Laghi, 2010), even to keep their rising debt under control (Broadbent, 2001; (Broadbent, 2001; Broadbent, Laughlin, 1999, 2002, 2004; Ricci, 2005; Eurostat, 2004).
The agreements regulating the different concession services in the recurring form of PPP (Parker, Gould, 1999; Pisani, 2001; Grimsey, Lewis, 2005; Guthrie, 2005), fall within the scope of IFRIC 12 (Campra, 2012: 2675) and the different accounting treatment of the operator’s rights on infrastructure, depending on the different tasks of control and regulation to be provided to the public on behalf of the public sector in accordance with the terms specified in the contract for a specified period of time (Hall, 2008), and on the identification and detection of the party on whom demand risk stays (Campra, Faraudello, Malfatti, Passarani, 2011),
The accounting treatment of "Service Concession Arrangements" (SCA), ruled by IFRIC 12, represents one of the most significant and emblematic cases of the application of the principle of the prevalence of substance over form (Meyer, 1976; Shere, 1986; Adwinckle, 1987), to highlight "typical light and shade" of a principle which is the basis of IAS/IFRS accounting model (Laghi, Giornetti, 2009; Laghi, 2010). It is a significant case because it falls within the definition perimeter of the concession services (SCA), all forms of public-private partnership and Project financing, particularly focused and copiously considered and debated in the business literature over the past fifteen years (Vecchi, Amatucci, 2008).
In the following paragraphs, business literature on different forms of PPP and SCA before and after the adoption of IFRIC 12 will be separately analyzed and reclassified, in order to determine the contribution that IFRIC 12 interpretation produced in favour of the improvement of the conceptual vagueness characterizing such instruments even under an increasing normative isomorphism (DiMaggio, Powell, 1983, 1991; Sullivan, Skelcher, 2002; Dickinson, Glasby, 2010).
PPP, SCA: The theoretical Framework "before" the application of IFRIC 12
"Service Concession Arrangements" (SCAs) refer to those forms of PPP projects through which a public sector entity (grantor), entrusts to a private sector entity (operator), the concession to construct or to operate a public work or infrastructure, in order to perform a public service in the public interest, upon consideration, and resulting in deep functional privatization processes (Pivato, 1958; Amaduzzi, 1978: 227; Caramiello, 1988: 546; De Robertis, 1992; Guatri, 1992: 498; Kunz, 1997; Perfolini, 1999; Dell'Atti, 2001; Rijna, 2010). The operator’s consideration may consist in a right to charge users of the public services (intangible asset), or in an unconditional contractual right to receive cash or another financial asset (financial asset) from or at the direction of the grantor for the construction services (Campra, 2011; Laghi, 2010).
The following table reproduces the critical success factors regarding PPP, from an international literature view, prior to the adoption of IFRIC 12.
Table 2: Reconstruction and classification of literature
Reconstruction and classification of literature
(Critical success factors, PPP Projects)
Critical success factors
|
Author
|
Strong Private consortium
|
Jefferies et al. (2002)
Tiong (1996)
Birnie (1999)
Savas (1987)
Savas (2000)
|
Appropriate risk allocation and risk sharing
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Grant (1996)
Bing L., Akintoye A., Edwards P. J., Hardcastle C. (2005) (2007)
|
Competitive procurement process
|
Jefferies et al. (2002)
Kopp (1997)
Gentry and Fernandez (1997)
|
Commitment/responsibility of private/public sector
|
Stonchouse et al. (1996)
Kanter (1999)
NAO (2001b)
|
In-depth and realistic cost/benefit assessment
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Brodic (1995)
Hambros (1999)
|
|
|
Technical feasibility project
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Tiong (1996)
Zantke and Mangels (1999)
|
Transparency in the procurement process
|
Jefferies et al. (2002)
Kopp (1997)
Gentry and Fernandez (1997)
|
Good governance
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Frilet (1997)
Badshah (1998)
|
Favourable legal frame work
|
Bennett (1998)
Boyfield (1992)
Stein (1995)
Jones et al. (1996)
DiMaggio, Powell (1983,1991)
Sullivan, Skelcher (2002)
|
Available financial market
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Jefferies et al. (2002)
McCarthy e Tiong (1991)
Akintoye et al. (2001b)
|
Political support
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Zhang et al. (1998)
|
Multi – benefits objectives
|
Grant (1996)
|
Involvement of the Government providing guarantees
|
Stonehouse et al. (1996)
Kanter (1999)
Qiao et al. (2001)
Zhang et al. (1998)
|
A healthy economic policy
|
EIB (2000)
|
Macroeconomic stability
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
Dailami e Klein (1997)
|
Well organized government
|
Boyfield (1992)
Stein (1995)
Jones et al. (1996)
Finnerty (1996)
|
Shared authority between the public and private sectors
|
Stonehouse at al. (1996)
Kanter (1999)
|
Social support
|
Frilet, 1997
|
Technology transfer
|
Qiao et al. (2001)
|
Share with your friends: |