Theoretical framework on Public Private Partnership and Service Concession Arrangement, before and after



Download 0.74 Mb.
Page2/5
Date26.11.2017
Size0.74 Mb.
#35087
1   2   3   4   5

Source: (CRESME, 2013)

Additionally, by aggregating the identified PPP 18 sectors into three main groups of interventions, we see an increasing emphasis on urban regeneration, meaning the set of regeneration interventions on built space, functional to improve the quality of life2. It is a market sector, triggered mainly by municipalities, which approximately represented 70% of demand and 17% of the total business volume between 2002 and 2012, and it was the only sector with a total positive balance sheet in 2012. Basic service sectors (transportation, health and education and social) and essential service sectors (water, energy, lighting, cemetery services, waste disposal) were the main sectors with reference to revenues, but during the last year these sectors registered a decline in the amounts linked to tender notices.



Compared to the size of PPPs, in 2012, works of less than 5 million euros continue to grow and investments have mainly covered initiatives of higher amount. The initiatives of less than 5 million euros were 1,553 corresponding to a total of 974 million, that are at odds respectively in number and amount, of 92% and 11% of the PPP total market when excluding the initiatives for which we do not know the value of the contract. The initiatives of more than 5 million euros, on the other hand, were just 127 (only 8% of demand) but their economic value exceeded the 7.7 billion equivalent to 89% of the total market of PPPs (in 2011 initiatives were 169 for 12.2 million euro equal to 92% of the market).
Table 1 – the macro fields of PPP: number and amount of races counted in 2002, 2005, 2008-2012 (amounts in millions of euros)


Source: www.infopieffe.it

























 

2002

2005

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Total2002-2012























































Races

Number




























Essential services

115

207

297

372

860

662

911

4.189

Basic services

33

38

131

168

175

195

212

1.150

Urban re generation

188

745

894

1.360

2.037

1.975

2.081

11.439

TOTAL__853,6__223,6__142,4__68,6'>TOTAL__336__990__1.322__1.900'>TOTAL

336

990

1.322

1.900

3.072

2.832

3.204

16.778




Variation %




12/’02

12/’05

12/’08

12/’09

12/’10

12/’11







Essential services

692,2

340,1

206,7

144,9

5,9

37,6







Basic services

542,4

457,9

61,8

26,2

21,1

8,7







Urban re generation

1.006,9

179,3

132,8

53,0

2,2

5,4







TOTAL

853,6

223,6

142,4

68,6

4,3

13,1










Amount(Mlns euro)




























Essential services

455

3.002

1.460

1.335

4.173

3.840

2.953

21.430

Basic services

349

1.764

3.525

3.162

4.751

8.277

4.524

37.627

Urban re generation

488

1.381

966

1.410

1.000

1.171

1.204

11.951

TOTAL

1.292

6.146

5.951

5.907

9.924

13.288

8.682

71.008




Variation %




12/’02

12/’05

12/’08

12/’09

12/’10

12/’11







Essential services

549,2

-1,6

102,3

121,2

-29,2

-23,1







Basic services

1.195,0

156,5

28,3

43,1

-4,8

-45,3







Urban re generation

147,0

-12,8

24,6

-14,6

20,4

2,9







TOTAL

572,1

41,3

45,9

47,0

-12,5

-34,7








THEORY-Elaboration of the reference theoretical framework

PPP, SCA and IFRIC 12: A literature survey

("Before" and "After" the application of IFRIC 12)
In some countries, infrastructure for services and public works (stadiums, kindergartens, roads, ports, airports, hospitals, cemeteries, prisons, parking lots, telecommunications networks, water distribution systems, networks for the supply of energy), is created, managed and controlled directly by the public sector taking care of the maintenance over time through direct financial allocations (Campra, 2005, 2012; Hall, 2008).

However, subsequent to the introduction of new stringent budgetary constraints, the respect of general government budgetary balances (Stability Pact in EU countries), and the increasing scarcity of resources, worsened by the financial crisis, in some countries, over the past twenty years, (Borgonovi, 2005, 2006, 2009; Amatucci, Vecchi 2009, 2011), governments have introduced (as shown in the following table), public-private partnership (PPP), through contractual service arrangements (Robinson 2001; Hawksworth, 2001), in order to attract private sector participation in the development, financing, operation and maintenance of works and utilities (Laghi, 2010), even to keep their rising debt under control (Broadbent, 2001; (Broadbent, 2001; Broadbent, Laughlin, 1999, 2002, 2004; Ricci, 2005; Eurostat, 2004).

The agreements regulating the different concession services in the recurring form of PPP (Parker, Gould, 1999; Pisani, 2001; Grimsey, Lewis, 2005; Guthrie, 2005), fall within the scope of IFRIC 12 (Campra, 2012: 2675) and the different accounting treatment of the operator’s rights on infrastructure, depending on the different tasks of control and regulation to be provided to the public on behalf of the public sector in accordance with the terms specified in the contract for a specified period of time (Hall, 2008), and on the identification and detection of the party on whom demand risk stays (Campra, Faraudello, Malfatti, Passarani, 2011),

The accounting treatment of "Service Concession Arrangements" (SCA), ruled by IFRIC 12, represents one of the most significant and emblematic cases of the application of the principle of the prevalence of substance over form (Meyer, 1976; Shere, 1986; Adwinckle, 1987), to highlight "typical light and shade" of a principle which is the basis of IAS/IFRS accounting model (Laghi, Giornetti, 2009; Laghi, 2010). It is a significant case because it falls within the definition perimeter of the concession services (SCA), all forms of public-private partnership and Project financing, particularly focused and copiously considered and debated in the business literature over the past fifteen years (Vecchi, Amatucci, 2008).

In the following paragraphs, business literature on different forms of PPP and SCA before and after the adoption of IFRIC 12 will be separately analyzed and reclassified, in order to determine the contribution that IFRIC 12 interpretation produced in favour of the improvement of the conceptual vagueness characterizing such instruments even under an increasing normative isomorphism (DiMaggio, Powell, 1983, 1991; Sullivan, Skelcher, 2002; Dickinson, Glasby, 2010).
PPP, SCA: The theoretical Framework "before" the application of IFRIC 12
"Service Concession Arrangements" (SCAs) refer to those forms of PPP projects through which a public sector entity (grantor), entrusts to a private sector entity (operator), the concession to construct or to operate a public work or infrastructure, in order to perform a public service in the public interest, upon consideration, and resulting in deep functional privatization processes (Pivato, 1958; Amaduzzi, 1978: 227; Caramiello, 1988: 546; De Robertis, 1992; Guatri, 1992: 498; Kunz, 1997; Perfolini, 1999; Dell'Atti, 2001; Rijna, 2010). The operator’s consideration may consist in a right to charge users of the public services (intangible asset), or in an unconditional contractual right to receive cash or another financial asset (financial asset) from or at the direction of the grantor for the construction services (Campra, 2011; Laghi, 2010).

The following table reproduces the critical success factors regarding PPP, from an international literature view, prior to the adoption of IFRIC 12.



Table 2: Reconstruction and classification of literature

Reconstruction and classification of literature

(Critical success factors, PPP Projects)

Critical success factors

Author

Strong Private consortium

Jefferies et al. (2002)

Tiong (1996)

Birnie (1999)

Savas (1987)

Savas (2000)

Appropriate risk allocation and risk sharing

Qiao et al. (2001)

Grant (1996)

Bing L., Akintoye A., Edwards P. J., Hardcastle C. (2005) (2007)


Competitive procurement process

Jefferies et al. (2002)

Kopp (1997)

Gentry and Fernandez (1997)

Commitment/responsibility of private/public sector

Stonchouse et al. (1996)

Kanter (1999)

NAO (2001b)

In-depth and realistic cost/benefit assessment

Qiao et al. (2001)

Brodic (1995)

Hambros (1999)







Technical feasibility project

Qiao et al. (2001)

Tiong (1996)

Zantke and Mangels (1999)

Transparency in the procurement process

Jefferies et al. (2002)

Kopp (1997)

Gentry and Fernandez (1997)

Good governance

Qiao et al. (2001)

Frilet (1997)

Badshah (1998)

Favourable legal frame work

Bennett (1998)

Boyfield (1992)

Stein (1995)

Jones et al. (1996)

DiMaggio, Powell (1983,1991)

Sullivan, Skelcher (2002)

Available financial market

Qiao et al. (2001)

Jefferies et al. (2002)

McCarthy e Tiong (1991)

Akintoye et al. (2001b)

Political support

Qiao et al. (2001)

Zhang et al. (1998)

Multi – benefits objectives

Grant (1996)

Involvement of the Government providing guarantees

Stonehouse et al. (1996)

Kanter (1999)

Qiao et al. (2001)

Zhang et al. (1998)

A healthy economic policy

EIB (2000)

Macroeconomic stability

Qiao et al. (2001)

Dailami e Klein (1997)

Well organized government

Boyfield (1992)

Stein (1995)

Jones et al. (1996)

Finnerty (1996)

Shared authority between the public and private sectors

Stonehouse at al. (1996)

Kanter (1999)

Social support

Frilet, 1997

Technology transfer

Qiao et al. (2001)


Download 0.74 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   2   3   4   5




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page