Foundation Briefs Advanced Level September/October Brief Resolved



Download 0.68 Mb.
Page18/29
Date20.10.2016
Size0.68 Mb.
#6219
1   ...   14   15   16   17   18   19   20   21   ...   29

Problems with “Sports Diplomacy”


Sports Diplomacy Organization SportsUnited is Wasteful AMS

Senator Tom Coburn. “Waste Book.” October 2012. http://www.coburn.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?a=Files.Serve&File_id=b7b23f66-2d60-4d5a-8bc5-8522c7e1a40e

SportsUnited is touted by the Department of State as being the premier sports exchange program for what the department calls “sports diplomacy.” Through this initiative, the Bureau of Educational and Cultural Affairs sends American professional athletes and coaches all around the world to “conduct drills, lead team building sessions, and engage youth in a dialogue on the importance of education, health, and respect for diversity.”

Taxpayers will spend [spent] $5.5 million on SportsUnited this year [in 2012]. Since 2005, the United States has sent over 220 athletes to more than 50 countries. Taxpayers have sent Major League Soccer player Tony Sanneh to Ethiopia, NBA players like Dikembe Mutumbo and George Gervin to Sudan and India, and a former WNBA star to China. SportsUnited also brings athletes from other countries to the United States as part of their Sport Visitors program. The program has brought nearly 1,000 international visitors since 2003. For example, the government paid for Tunisian swimmers’ trip to the U.S. Olympic Swimming Trials this summer. Taxpayer dollars also paid for track and field athletes to travel from the Caribbean to Oregon and beach volleyball players from Russia to southern California. In our current fiscal climate, investing scarce resources in overseas trips for high-paid, jet- setting professional athletes should not be a high priority for the federal government”

The Holdout Problem


How Sports Stadium Construction Causes Economic Problems AMS

Rasmussen, Spencer. “The Holdout Problem.” Duke University. 2014. http://sites.duke.edu/urbaneconomics/?p=1088

The Holdout Problem: “is a form of monopoly power that potentially arises in the course of land assembly.  Once assembly begins, individual owners, knowing their land is essential to the completion of the project, can hold out for prices in excess of their opportunity costs” or “individual owners, realizing that they can impose substantial costs on the developer, seek prices well in excess of their true reservation prices.”

A holdout problem must require assembly, which is the need for at least two distinct properties for a development.



Result: Large-scale projects that require assembly, like housing developments, parks and open spaces, stadiums or shopping malls, will have high bargaining costs.  This will create incentives for developers to look for land where ownership is less dispersed, which will minimize assembly.  This will lead to these large building projects taking place on the fringes of cities leading to unnecessary urban sprawl In order to combat urban sprawl…

i.           Developers can maintain their secrecy about projects by utilizing dummy buyers to help acquire assemblies.  This would be useful because sellers would not know that a single buyer is attempting all of the land in a certain area.  This is more difficult for government-backed projects because they often require openness.

ii.          Governments can create incentives or subsidies for building in city centers or disincentives for building in the suburbs.  The justification for this can come from redevelopment of central areas.

iii.         The use of eminent domain, but this often raises issues about whether or not a private organization should be able to benefit from the use of eminent domain.

The holdout problem “represents a situation where landowners whose property is essential to the completion of some large development project to seek to block completion of the project in an effort to extract monopoly rents” This biases development away from areas where ownership is the most dispersed, city centers, and towards areas where ownership is more concentrated, the fringes or suburbs of cities.


Opportunity Costs of Public Funding for Pro Sports


Stadium construction saddles governments with annual debt DAT

Thomas, Louisa. “Up and Running.” Grantland. 5 November 2012. Web. http://grantland.com/features/examining-outrage-cancelation-new-york-city-marathon/

If we’re going to talk about the abuse of public resources for sports — and we should! — we should give our attention where attention is due. Only three NFL stadiums were built without public funding, and two of those three used public funds for upgrades. (Only the Jets’ and Giants’ MetLife Stadium, as it happens, was privately built.) Yankee Stadium cost taxpayers $321.5 million. The Yankees are the country’s richest sports team (along with the Cowboys, who play in a stadium built in part with tax-free borrowing). According to Bloomberg (hello!) Businessweek, the U.S. Treasury loses $146 million a year on municipal bonds with tax-free interest issued for sports structures. The taxpayer subsidies to bondholders on the $17 billion tax-exempt debt on stadiums built in the last 27 years will be $4 billion. You know what would be a better use of $4 billion? Repairing roads, building sea walls, preparing for the next big storm.



Stadium construction is pitched as a one-off expense: pay for the stadium, and watch decades of economic dividends roll in. The problem is that the contractual details of public-private stadium construction partnerships often negate the tax burden of the teams building stadiums and shifts financial responsibility to public entities instead.
Publically-funded stadiums financed by reallocation still tax cities’ citizens DAT

Pay and Play and Pay Some More.” The Economist. 19 November 2013. Web. http://www.economist.com/blogs/democracyinamerica/2013/11/stadium-financing

The Braves complained that Turner Field needed $150m in "infrastructure work alone", which would not "significantly enhance the fan experience". The new location puts them closer to more of their season-ticket holders, most of whom come from the city's rich northern suburbs.

Here's how it will work: the Braves will buy 60 acres of land, and give 15 of them to the Cobb County stadium authority. Those 15 acres, on which the stadium and 2,000 parking spaces will be built, will be exempt from property taxes. The Braves will develop the rest into a "mixed-use, 365-day destination", on which they will pay tax and from which, of course, they will keep the revenue. Cobb County will pay around $300m over the next 30 years. Relative pittances will come from those old stadium slush funds: taxes on rental cars and hotels. Mayors love them because they can tell their constituents that only visitors will pay them, though in Cobb's case that doesn't quite hold up. Visitors may be paying for hotels, but probably not for rental cars—Cobb is too far from the airport. Increased hotel and property taxes in the area to be developed around the stadium will add more, but the bulk—$260m over the next 30 years—will come from a "reallocation" of existing property-tax revenues. This lets Cobb's executive boast that there will be no property tax increases.

That is technically true, but essentially malarkey: the reallocated taxes are currently paying for parks, and were due to sunset in 2017 or 2018. So homeowners may not pay more in the future than they pay today, but they will pay more in the future than they otherwise would have. And this does not even consider what else the county could have done with that $260m, had they decided to keep the tax in place and not funnel it into a sports team's already-deep pockets. Neil deMause at the invaluable Field of Schemes blog explains that Cobb taxpayers are probably looking at losses as high as $200m. Kasim Reed, Atlanta's mayor and an expert knife-twister, told a press conference that "we can't spend money that liberally in the city of Atlanta. We are fiscal conservatives here." (Of course, Atlanta will throw hundreds of millions of public dollars at a new stadium for their football team, but better one white elephant, I suppose, than two.)



In Atlanta’s case, the city is essentially taking money from parks & rec to funnel it into for-profit private enterprise, with its own citizens footing a potential $200 million bill down the line. Especially for otherwise fiscally conservative counties, this is money that likely won’t be reallocated again back to its original intended purposes.
Pro sports funding is a false dilemma DAT

Jeffrey G. Owen. “The Intangible Benefits of Sports Teams.” Indiana State University. Public Finance and Management, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 321-345. 2006. Web. http://www.cas.unt.edu/~jhauge/Teaching/Sports/Owen.pdf

Assume for a moment that we actually know with certainty residents’ true valuations of teams exceed the construction costs of stadiums. This would still not necessarily lead to the conclusion that such subsidies are correct public policy. Just because consumers are willing to pay a certain amount for a good does not mean that they have to or should have to. If professional sports at the same level of quality can be provided without a subsidy to the team, this is obviously better for the city. Public policy should be to attempt to provide sports teams at the least possible cost, which could mean contributing nothing to the construction of stadiums if a team can operate profitably when paying the full cost of the playing facility. Even the most accurate contingent value survey would only give a reservation price for the cities.



With the Tax Reform Act of 1986, cities are inadvertently incentivized to not aim for “least possible cost.” Cities are encouraged to ensure that less than 10% of stadium financing is repaid by stadium revenue, leaving cities on the hook for the remaining debt. This escalates cities’ bid offers; allowing teams to overstep the 10% line precludes cities’ issued bonds from being tax-free.
Funding for stadiums comes at the expense of better options, Fj

DeMause, Neil. “Do cities gain from subsidizing sports teams?” Al Jazeera America. August 21, 2013.

Humphreys, in fact, says that operating subsidies like those handed out to the Coyotes and Pacers are likely to get even less bang for the buck than stadium cash, which at least might create a few thousand temporary construction jobs. "Not only that, but the operating subsidies are almost certainly coming out of general fund revenues," he says. "If there's a ticket tax or anything that looks like a user tax, at least then the people who are enjoying the benefits are paying. But if it's operating subsidies coming out of general fund revenues, that's money that could go to any other alternative use in the city, like education or public safety."

Even public money with strings attached could go to fill other city needs, say budget watchdogs. Ryan Splitlog of Common Cause Georgia, a nonprofit, nonpartisan citizens' lobby, notes that the money going to the Falcons comes from hotel-motel tax revenue that is designated for promoting tourism and convention business. "I think you could paint with a pretty wide brush stroke when talking about what that means for the city of Atlanta," he says, suggesting fixing the "atrocious" roads and sidewalks in the blocks surrounding the convention center campus as one example. "You could talk about infrastructure projects that improve the quality of life for people who actually live here. I think the public would get much more behind something like that."
Baltimore’s new publically-funded stadium complex ravaged industrially-valuable areas DAT

Chapin, Timothy. “Sports Facilities as Urban Redevelopment Catalysts. Journal of the American Planning Association, Vol. 70, No. 2, Spring 2004.Web.

Somewhat perversely, instead of new development being catalyzed in the immediate district, areas surrounding Camden Yards have seen the opposite: clearing of land for surface parking lots (E. Cline, personal communication, May, 1998). These lots have spread into the Camden Industrial District to serve the massive influx of automobiles and buses on event days. The Maryland Stadium Authority has purchased or leased a number of parcels in the Camden Industrial District and paved them over for event parking (see Figure 2), much to the chagrin of local planners. Attendees also park on other undeveloped parcels, as well as along the streets of this district on event days. City planning staff expressed concern with the infiltration of parking because the city has promoted industrial and manufacturing development in this district, an area that remains best suited for industrial uses U. French and J. Leviton, personal communication, August, 1998).

(…)

From the above it might be suggested that Camden Yards has experienced some success as an urban redevelopment catalyst. However, such a conclusion overlooks the fact that Baltimore's Inner Harbor flourished long before Camden Yards was built. Camden Yards did not create the success that is Inner Harbor; it simply incorporated roughly 20 formerly industrial blocks into the postmodern tourist economy. Camden Yards offers yet another destination in downtown Baltimore, but one that remains disconnected from many of the neighborhoods surrounding it. The old retail district to the north remains disengaged from the downtown entertainment economy; revitalization of this area will likely result from the expansion of the UM-B campus and not Camden Yards. Similarly, Sharp- Leadenhall and Pigtown remain largely untouched by the crowds and dollars spent at Camden Yards, except for local entrepreneurs charging event attendees $20-40 to park in these neighborhoods during events.



The direct local impact is striking in the above card: reduced economic viability and no direct benefits (correlative or causative).
Opportunity cost does not need to be financial. ASF

Kahn, Aron. "Minnesota Lawmakers Debate Stadium Quality-of-Life Issue" Knight Ridder Tribune. April 28, 2004. http://www.highbeam.com/doc/1G1-115980642.html/print

The Tax Committee vote is expected to come Friday or early next week, and it might be close. Abrams said that if the committee turns down the measure, the issue is dead for the session, despite the many methods traditionally available to revive bills.

But it appeared the chairman and supporters alike coalesced behind the notion that the two teams do contribute to the quality of life in Minnesota.

"My kids and I are all the time talking sports," Art Rolnick, an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank in Minneapolis, testified before the committee. That quality-of- life issue is worth something, he said, but a public investment in early childhood education is far more important, he said. "Hands down."



Rolnick said the best way to measure the quality-of-life quotient is a referendum of affected voters. Most stadium bill supporters oppose referendums on the grounds that they would delay or potentially nullify the projects.

If people cannot vote on a stadium that may displace them, this directly costs them access to education, which is a key necessity in social mobility. The tradeoff here is not necessarily economic, but rather direct access to education.





Download 0.68 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   14   15   16   17   18   19   20   21   ...   29




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page