Link Don’t buy their democracy link – it’s outdated. Their evidence is predicated on democracy promotion in the Clinton and Bush administrations – under Obama, democracy promotion does not necessitate the expansion of liberal capitalism
Kurki, PhD @ University of Wales, Professor in International Relations Theory @ University of Wales, Aberystwyth, 13 Feb 2013
(Milja, “Politico-Economic Models of Democracy in Democracy Promotion,” International Studies Perspectives, pg 14)//SG
Clearly, there have been some important rhetorical shifts in the democracy promoters’ understanding of democracy in the last few years. The crisis of democracy promotion and of Western economic performance has forced some rhetorical redirection to take place in democracy promotion. The Obama admin- istration has moved away from a Hayekian line embedded in both Clinton’s democracy promotion agenda (Hippler 1995:13) and Bush’s freedom agenda (White House 2009) toward a more cautious “developmental” approach, which generally down-grades the high-flying democracy rhetoric of the Bush years and, crucially, ties democracy’s success to successful economic development more generally. Yet, this shift has not been, it seems, conceptualized in as clear terms as this article would recommend. It follows that continuities and also incoheren- cies exist: While renewed emphasis is placed in the Obama administration on democracy as a way of supporting “religious freedoms” and “workers rights”, suggesting reform liberal avenues, democracy is still associated with “peace”, “open markets”, and “prosperity”, revealing continuing liberal, if “reform liberal” inclinations (State Department 2010). Thus, the Obama administration has abandoned the rhetorical edge of Hayekian kind it seems: Liberal capitalism and democracy are still seen as conjoined but the linkage between the two is not seen as tight and necessary in the same sense as under Bush (economic free- dom > democracy). But has a clear alternative account emerged—complemen- tarian or otherwise? No, rather there has been a shift toward an incredibly vague treatment of the capitalism–democracy relationship. Instead of advancing a narrow Hayekian line, the discourse now simply states the complementariness of these ideals, without specifying the logic on the basis of which these two systems are linked together. The same trends toward “vagueness through rhetorical revisions” are evident in the European Union: The European Commission has increasingly moved toward a somewhat more discursively open and social justice-oriented develop- ment and human rights policy (see e.g. European Community 2006). Yet the precise meaning of capitalism–democracy relationship is left vague and open. Having moved from a confident assertion of liberal markets and democracy, the Union is somewhat apologetically insisting on their complementary relationship but without specifying the logic, causal or philosophical, for their interconnec- tions. The language of social democracy and participatory democracy thrown in to the discourse does not help to clarify what kind of a logic on this relationship the European Union stands for. There are real limits then to the rethinking of politico-economic models of democracy promotion in current democracy promotion practice. Many of these seem to be set by the lack of clear reference points in terms of alternative con- ceptual or theoretical frameworks to appeal to. While the Hayekian line seems too much, it is unclear for these liberal actors what they should put in its place.
No Link: Cuba Tourism No Link – Tourism in Cuba will not change Cuban economic policies
Carmona - Professor of Economics at the Universidad San Pablo. Spring 2000
(Antonio, “Cuba: Reforms and Adjustments Versus Transition,” International Journal of Political Economy. Vol 30.1, pp. 93-94. JSTOR)//SG
Tourism accounts for the greatest dollar accumulation in Cuba. In 1997, there were over 1.2 millionvisitorsdue to this industry whobrought in approximately U.S.$1 billion. Cuba's dependency on tourism continues to grow and simulate prerevolution economics; ofcourse, the difference here is thattourism remains in the hands o f the Cuban government and not solely U.S. enterprises. In 1996, Castro made his comment on tourism and the economy. He stated thattourism would not change the economic culture in Cuba or replace the other traditional economies, whereas in the Fifth PCC Congress tourism turned out to be the salvation o f the Cuban economy. This salvation, however, brings with it other social problems like prostitution, access to drugs from abroad, and violent theft. So far, state control of these problems has manifested itself in the form of police repression.42
Neolib Good Alt Worse The alt fails – their movement against hegemonic centers and neoliberalism is the root cause of the problems they critique. Their over-simplification of the world serves as the jumping point for the expansion of poverty and social exclusion which exacerbates economic crises
Spring 08, Professor and researcher at the National University of Mexico; the first MRF-Chair on Social Vulnerability at United National University Institute for Environment and Human Security, 2008
(Ursula Oswald, “Globalization from Below: Social Movements and Altermundism — Reconceptualizing Security from a Latin American Perspective,” Globalization and Environmental Challenges - Hexagon Series on Human and Environmental Security and Peace, 2008, Vol 3, 388-91. SpringerLink.)//SG
There is another explanation, shared in the South, which links up the structural poverty and regressive globalization with the upsurge of social movements, struggling against the hegemonic centres and the im- position of their neoliberal model, the exploitation of natural resources and the destruction of social net- works, and cultural and immaterial goods. This expla- nation is related to Latin America, where during 1968 students started revolutions for wider political partic- ipation and democratization. In 1971 the peasant cen- tre Túpac Katari was founded in Ecuador, and in 1974 the first indigenous congress took place in San Cristóbal de las Casas in Chiapas, Mexico. The progress of social exclusion led in Mexico to the first economic crisis in 1976, followed by other countries in LA, Asia, and Africa. They aggravated the survival of the poor and induced a massive migration process from the rural areas to the towns, which is still under- way, above all in India and China. Later, as a result of several military coups, in 1977 a long campaign of the Mothers of the Plaza de Mayo in Buenos Aires started, and in 1979 together with the foundation of the MST the first land occupation occurred in Brazil in the Fazenda Malai in Rio Grande do Sul. In the same year the Trade Union of Workers and Peasants (CSUT-CB) was founded in Bolivia, later transformed into Central Obrera Boliviana (COB), and in Mexico the Independent National Peasant Movement Plan de Ayala (CNPA). All these social movements of the in- digenous, peasants, workers, and women, relied on their internal resources coming from communities able to create their proper and independent space of struggle. The consolidation of alternative processes was brutally repressed, e.g. in the 1968 student massacre in Tlatelolco, Mexico; in 1954 by a military coup and dic- tatorship16 in Guatemala and Paraguay; later in 1964 in Brazil; 1968 in Panama; 1970 in Bolivia; 1973 in Chile and Uruguay; 1976 in Ecuador and Argentina, 1991 in Haiti and 1992 in Venezuela. In addition there were civil and guerrilla wars in Central America, in Colombia, Peru, Brazil, Argentina, Ecuador, Mexico and in other countries. The massacres against the in- digenous people and ethnocide in Colombia, Guate- mala, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Peru reinforced repres- sion (Tlatelolco, Mexico; Uruguay, Guatemala, El Salvador, and Paraguay). In different parts of Latin America the movements understood during the 1980’s that it was necessary to train and educate their mem- bers in order to create stable organizations able to transform society from the inside. Health and educa- tion together with food sovereignty was picked up by most movements. MST consolidated its organization with 4 million members and it is supported by addi- tional 480,000 families. MST set up 3,000 camps for landless peasants and established 1,500 schools, eacher training colleges and the peasant university Florestan Fernandes. Their philosophy which influ- enced deeply Via Campesina (2005) and the WSF is “the question of power can not be resolved by the oc- cupation of the palest, which is the easiest thing, but by creating new social relations” according to Pedro Stédile, a leader of MST. Transformation of the soci- ety is not like a reality show, that are often transmitted on television, but a transformation of daily life in the place where the people live, work, and meet; the pub- lic space where the system of domination and exploi- tation is understood in any action and imposition.
Rebelling against neoliberalism inevitably leads to a violent struggle characterized by the struggle to meet basic needs.
Ceceña, Professor at the National Autonomous University of Mexico, 2009(Ana Esther, National Autonomous University of Mexico; Director of the ObservatorioLatinoamericano de Geopolítica and active in the Americas Demilitarisation Campaign, “Postneoliberalism and its bifurcations” Development Dialogue Issue 51, http://rosalux-europa.info/userfiles/file/DD51.pdf#page=35)//CS
Both things have happened after 30 years of neoliberalism. The voraciousness of the market took the appropriation of nature and the dispossession of human beings to the extreme. Territories were ravaged by desertification and their inhabitants driven out. People revolted, and ecological catastrophe, which had reached an extreme point of irreversibility, started to manifest itself in a violent way. People rebelled against the advance of capitalism, blocking the ways that were taking it towards even greater appropriation. Armed insurgencies impeded access to the rainforest; civil revolts put an end to the building of dams, to intensive mining, to the construction of heavy-load roads, to the privatisation of oil and gas, and to the monopolisation of water. The market, by itself, was not able to defeat those people who were already out of its reach because they had been expelled; and from there, from the non-market, they were struggling for human and natural life, for life’s essential elements, for another relationship with nature, for an end to the pillaging. The end of neoliberalism begins when the extent of dispossession arouses the fury of the people and compels them to burst onto the scene.
Positive political change occurs only within neoliberalism—notions of revolution are romantic ideals
Barnett, Professor of Geography at The Open University 05-- (Clive, “The consolations of ‘neoliberalism’”, Geoforum 36:1, 2005, http://oro.open.ac.uk/26332/1/consolations_of_neoliberalism2.pdf)//AS
Recent theories of “neoliberalism” have retreated from the appreciation of the longterm rhythms of socio-cultural change, which Stuart Hall once developed in his influential account of Thatcherism as a variant of authoritarian populism. Instead, they favour elite-focused analyses of state bureaucracies, policy networks, and the like.One consequence of the residualization of the social is that theories of “neoliberalism” have great difficulty accounting for, or indeed even in recognizing, new forms of “individualized collective-action” (Marchetti 2003) that have emerged in tandem with the apparent ascendancy of “neoliberal hegemony”:environmental politics and the politics of sustainability; new forms of consumer activism oriented by an ethics of assistance and global solidarity; the identity politics of sexuality related to demands for changes in modes of health care provision, and so on (see Norris 2002). All of these might be thought of as variants of what we might want to call bottom-up governmentality. This refers to the notion that non-state and non-corporate actors are also engaged in trying to govern various fields of activity, both by acting on the conduct and contexts of ordinary everyday life, but also by acting on the conduct of state and corporate actors as well. Rose (1999, 281-284) hints at the outlines of such an analysis, at the very end of his paradigmatic account of governmentality, but investigation of this phenomenon is poorly developed at present. Instead, the troublefree amalgamation of Foucault’s ideas into the Marxist narrative of “neoliberalism” sets up a simplistic image of the world divided between the forces of hegemony and the spirits of subversion (see Sedgwick 2003, 11-12). And clinging to this image only makes it all the more difficult to acknowledge the possibility of positive political action that does not conform to a romanticized picture of rebellion, contestation, or protest against domination (see Touraine 2001).
Good: Wealth redistribution/Class hierarchy Globalization and neoliberalism empirically increase welfare spending and redistribution of wealth
Rudra, Associate Professor of International Affairs at the University of Pittsburgh 02 (Nita, “Globalization and the Decline of the Welfare State in Less-Developed Countries”, International Organization 56:2, Spring 2002, JSTOR)//AS
Conventional wisdom suggests that all states, regardless of their partisan com- positions and national differences, would embrace neoliberal policies in order to maintain international competitiveness in a globalizing world." Consequently, the demise of the welfare state is expected for two reasons. First, generous welfare benefits are not regarded as good market-disciplining devices on labor. Both the resulting upward pressures on labor costs and the dampening effects on work incentives are claimed to adversely affect export competitiveness. Second, global- ization discourages governments from raising revenue. "Footloose capital," or the capacity to withdraw and shift both productive and financial capital with greater ease, has made it increasingly difficult for governments to generate revenues through taxation." This "race to the neoliberal bottom" in tax rates is compounded by governments' lowering taxes to compete with other states for international investors and to prevent capital flight. By the same token, state borrowing, which leads to higher debt and interest rates, also deters investment. The last two decades have thus become witness to the reification of Charles LindbIom`s "markets as prisons" idea." With increasing global competition, governments supposedly find it more difficult to protect citizens from market-generated risks and inequalities. By analyzing fourteen OECD countries, Geoffrey Garrett presents the most recent and convincing challenge to the notion that welfare states are crumbling under these pressures." Garrett"˜s analysis extends the globalization-welfare debate initiated by Karl Polyani, Jolm Gerard Ruggie, and Peter J. Katzenstein.'5 He demonstrates that international market exposure actually induces greater government spending on redistribution programs that compensate for market-generated inequalities. Key to Garrett"˜s analysis is the ability of labor-market institutions to effectively negotiate between government and labor. He convincingly argues that if labor markets are highly centralized and well developed, then labor and government can effectively coordinate economic performance with redistribution policies. He concludes that globalization has in fact strengthened left-labor movements, and, consequently, cross-national partisan differences in the developed world have been sustained.
Neoliberal policies have led to an era of enormous economic and social progress
Navarro,M.D., Ph.D., Professor of Public Policy, Sociology, and Policy Studies at Johns Hopkins University, 2007
(Vicente, “NEOLIBERALISM AS A CLASS IDEOLOGY; OR, THE POLITICAL CAUSES OF THE GROWTH OF INEQUALITIES,” International Journal of Health Services, Vol. 37.1, pp47-49)//SG
A trademark of our times is the dominance of neoliberalism in the major economic, political, and social forums of the developed capitalist countries and in the international agencies they influence—including the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the World Bank, theWorld Trade Organization (WTO), and the technical agencies of the United Nations, such as theWorld Health Organization (WHO), Food and Agriculture Organization, and UNICEF. Starting in the United States during the Carter administration, neoliberalism expanded its influence through the Reagan administration and, in the United Kingdom, the Thatcher administration,to become an international ideology. Neoliberalism holds to a theory (though not necessarily a practice) that posits the following: 1. The state (or what is wrongly referred to in popular parlance as “the government”) needs to reduce its interventionism in economic and social activities. 2. Labor and financial markets need to be deregulated in order to liberate the enormous creative energy of the markets. 3. Commerce and investments need to be stimulated by eliminating borders and barriers to allow for the full mobility of labor, capital, goods, and services. Following these three tenets,according to neoliberal authors, we have seen that the worldwide implementation of such practices has led to the development of a “new” process: a globalization of economic activity that has generated a period of enormous economic growth worldwide, associated with a new era of social progress.For the first time in history, we are told, we are witnessing a worldwide economy, in which states are losing power and are being replaced by a worldwide market centered in multinational corporations, which are the main units of economic activity in the world today.This celebration of the process of globalization is also evident among some sectors of the left. Michael Hardt and Antonio Negri, in their widely cited Empire (1), celebrate the great creativity of what they consider to be a new era of capitalism. This new era, they claim, breaks with obsolete state structures and establishes a new international order,which they define as an imperialist order. They further postulate that this new imperialist order is maintained without any state dominating or being hegemonic in that order. Thus, they write (1, p. 39):We want to emphasize that the establishment of empire is a positive step towards the elimination of nostalgic activities based on previous power structures; we reject all political strategies that want to take us back to past situations such as the resurrection of the nation-state in order to protect the population from global capital. We believe that the new imperialist order is better than the previous system in the same way that Marx believed that capitalism was a mode of production and a type of society superior to the mode that it replaced. This point of view held by Marx was based on a healthy despisement of the parochial localism and rigid hierarchies that preceded the capitalist society, as well as on the recognition of the enormous potential for liberation that capitalism had. Globalization (i.e., the internationalization of economic activity according to neoliberal tenets)becomes, in Hardt and Negri’s position,an international system that is stimulating a worldwide activity that operates without any state or statesleading or organizing it. Such an admiring and flattering view of globalization andneoliberalism explains the positive reviews that Empire has received from EmilyEakin, a book reviewer for the New York Times, and other mainstream critics, notknown for sympathetic reviews of books that claim to derive their theoreticalposition from Marxism. Actually, Eakin describes Empire as the theoreticalframework that the world needs to understand its reality
Capitalism is key to challenging dominant social orders
Lipschutz, Professor of Politics at the University of California at Santa Cruz 07 (Ronnie, “CAPITALISM, CONFLICT AND CHURN: HOW THE AMERICAN CULTURE WAR WENT GLOBAL”, Conflicts and Tensions, 2007, Sage Publications, http://www.ic.ucsc.edu/~rlipsch/pol160A/Anheier.pdf)//AS
I begin with a general discussion of the relationship between culture, conflict, and globalization. I argue, from an historical materialist perspective, that capitalism eats away at the foundations of social structures and hierarchies through the ‘creative destruction’ and ‘churn’ that it generates, in the present case linked to globalization (Schumpeter 1942; see also Cox and Alm 1992; Boo 2004a, 2004b). Churn weakens the ideologies and relations that naturalize and justify particular institutionalized forms of domination, social organization and hegemony. When these begin to erode, the legitimacy of a social order comes under challenge. One result is cultural conflict, of the sort we see in America today. In the second part of the chapter, I give a brief historical account of this phenomenon in the United States, beginning with challenges to Puritanism in the 1730s and ending with the current religious revival and cultural conflict that began during the 1970s.This cycle is important because, since the early eighteenth century, there have been interesting, if mostly unremarked, cultural-religious conflicts correlated with phases of global capitalist expansion and social change. In this section, I also extend my analysis from the territory of the United States to the ROW (Rest of the World). I argue that the great, world-girdling struggle(s) of the early twenty-first century, between ‘freedom’ and ‘terror’, might be better seen as the latest episode in recurrent patterns of cultural conflict within the American social system, now extended beyond the country’s borders. Finally, I conclude with some theoretical speculations on the arguments presented in this chapter.
Good: Peace Capitalism empirically prevents war—no motive for expansion, overlap in national goals, and global market competition—data supports
Gartzke, associate professor of political science and a member of the Saltzman Institute of War and Peace Studies, 07 (Erik, “The Capitalist Peace”, American Journal of Political Science 51:1, 1/07, JSTOR)//AS
The discovery that democracies seldom fight each other has led, quite reasonably, to the conclusion that democ- racy causes peace, at least within the community of liberal polities. Explanations abound, but a consensus account of the dyadic democratic peace has been surprisingly slow to materialize. I offer a theory of liberal peace based on capi- talism and common interstate interests. Economic devel- opment, capital market integration, and the compatibility of foreign policy preferences supplant the effect of democ- racy in standard statistical tests of the democratic peace. In fact, after controlling for regional heterogeneity, any one of these three variables is sufficient to account for effects previously attributed to regime type in standard samples of wars, militarized interstate disputes (MIDs), and fatal disputes.' If war is a product of incompatible interests and failed or abortive bargaining, peace ensues when states lack dif- ferences worthy of costly conflict, or when circumstances favor successful diplomacy. Realists and others argue that state interests are inherently incompatible, but this need be so only if state interests are narrowly defined or when conquest promises tangible benefits. Peace can result from at least three attributes of mature capitalist economies. First, the historic impetus to territorial expansion is tempered by the rising importance of intellectual and financial capital, factors that are more expediently enticed than conquered. Land does little to increase the worth of the advanced economies while resource competition is more cheaply pursued through markets than by means of military occupation. At the same time, development actually increases the ability of states to project power when incompatible policy objectives exist. Development affects who states fight (and what they fight over) more than the overall frequency of warfare. Second, substantial overlap in the foreign policy goals of developed nations in the post-World War II period further limits the scope and scale of conflict. Lacking territorial tensions, consensus about how to order the international system has allowed liberal states to cooperate and to accommodate minor differences. Whether this affinity among liberal states will persist in the next century is a question open to debate. Finally, the rise of global capital markets creates a new mechanism for competition and communication for states that might otherwise be forced to fight. Separately, these processes influence patterns of warfare in the modern world. Together, they explain the absence of war among states in the developed world and account for the dyadic observation of the democratic peace. The notion of a capitalist peace is hardly new. Montesquieu, Paine, Bastiat, Mill, Cobden, Angell, and othersaw in market forces the power to end war. Unfortu- nately, war continued, leading many to view as overly op- timistic classical conceptions of liberal peace. This study can be seen as part of an effort to reexamine capitalist peace theory, revising arguments in line with contempo- rary insights much as Kantian claims were reworked in response to evolving evidence of a democratic peace. Existing empirical research on the democratic peace, while addressing many possible alternatives, provides an incomplete and uneven treatment of liberal economic processes. Most democratic peace research examines trade in goods and services but ignores capital markets and of- fers only a cursory assessment of economic development (Maoz and Russett 1992). Several studies explore the im- pact of interests, though these have largely been dismissed by democratic peace advocates (Oneal and Russett 1999a; Russett and Oneal 2001). These omissions or oversights help to determine the democratic peace result and thus shape subsequent research, thinking, and policy on the subject of liberal peace. This study offers evidence that liberal economic processes do in fact lead to peace, even accounting for the well-documented role of liberal pol- itics. Democracy cohabitates with peace. It does not, by itself, lead nations to be less conflict prone, not even to- ward other democracies. The argument and evidence provided here are bound to draw criticism. Skepticism in the face of controversial claims is natural, reasonable, even essential for the cumu- lation of knowledge. The democratic peace observation is supported by an exceptionally large and sophisticated body of research.2 At the same time, excessive deference to previous conclusions privileges conventional wisdom.3 A willingness to doubt that which we have come to believe is a hallmark of scientific inquiry. Indeed, the weight of existing evidence does not directly contradict this study as previous research has typically failed to address the claims of classical liberal political economists like Mon- tesquieu, Richard Cobden, and Norman Angell. As with previous research, this study finds support for a liberal peace, though the key causal variables, and some major policy implications, are considerably changed.
Neoliberalism is the chief pacifying and stabilizing force in Latin America
Parish and Peceny, Professors of Political Science ,University of New Mexico, respectively 02--
(Randall and Mark, “Kantian Liberalism and the Collective Defense of Democracy in Latin America”, Journal of Peace Research 39:2, 2002, http://jpr.sagepub.com.proxy.lib.umich.edu/content/39/2/229.full.pdf)//AS
We argue that systemic forces are becoming increasingly important in shaping a liberal peace in the inter-American system. Only in the past decade has this system taken on a consistently liberal character. The prevalence of authoritarian governments, insular economic models, and US preoccupation with Cold War security meant that the system rarely functioned as a liberal union prior to the 1990s. Today, however, nearly all Latin American states are governed by directly elected civilian regimes. The Organization of American States (OAS), the principal international institution in the region, is therefore composed almost entirely of liberal states for the first time in its history. In addition, virtually every state in the region has embraced liberal economic reforms and full integration into global markets. Finally, the system’s strongest power, the United States, behaves more like a liberal state in the post-Cold War era, actively promoting multilateral cooperation and democratic institutions. Together, a stronger OAS, increasing trade interdependence, and a more liberal regional hegemony have brought about an unprecedented transformation of the inter-American system. While a variety of studies have begun to emphasize these factors (Farer, 1996; Lowenthal&Treverton, 1994; Pastor, 1992; Remmer, 1993), none has fully integrated them in a theoretical framework that draws explicitly on the liberal argument.
Capitalism promotes peace and makes war less desirable
Bandow, A senior fellow at the Cato Institute and served as special assistant to President Reagan,2005, (Doug, “Spreading Capitalism Is Good for Peace” Cato Institute http://www.cato.org/publications/commentary/spreading-capitalism-is-good-peace)//JS
The shift from statist mercantilism to high-tech capitalism has transformed the economics behind war. Markets generate economic opportunities that make war less desirable. Territorial aggrandizement no longer provides the best path to riches. Free-flowing capital markets and other aspects of globalization simultaneously draw nations together and raise the economic price of military conflict. Moreover, sanctions, which interfere with economic prosperity, provides a coercive step short of war to achieve foreign policy ends.Positive economic trends are not enough to prevent war, but then, neither is democracy. It long has been obvious that democracies are willing to fight, just usually not each other. Contends Gartzke, “liberal political systems, in and of themselves, have no impact on whether states fight.” In particular, poorer democracies perform like non-democracies. He explains: “Democracy does not have a measurable impact, while nations with very low levels of economic freedom are 14 times more prone to conflict than those with very high levels.” Gartzke considers other variables, including alliance memberships, nuclear deterrence, and regional differences.Although the causes of conflict vary, the relationship between economic liberty and peace remains. His conclusion hasn’t gone unchallenged. Author R.J. Rummel, an avid proponent of the democratic peace theory, challenges Gartzke’s methodology and worries that it “may well lead intelligent and policy-wise analysts and commentators to draw the wrong conclusions about the importance of democratization.” Gartzke responds in detail, noting that he relied on the same data as most democratic peace theorists. If it is true that democratic states don’t go to war, then it also is true that “states with advanced free market economies never go to war with each other, either.” The point is not that democracy is valueless. Free political systems naturally entail free elections and are more likely to protect other forms of liberty - civil and economic, for instance.However, democracy alone doesn’t yield peace. To believe is does is dangerous: There’s no panacea for creating a conflict-free world.That doesn’t mean that nothing can be done. But promoting open international markets - that is, spreading capitalism - is the best means to encourage peace as well as prosperity.Notes Gartzke: “Warfare among developing nations will remain unaffected by the capitalist peace as long as the economies of many developing countries remain fettered by governmental control.” Freeing those economies is critical.It’s a particularly important lesson for the anti-capitalist left. For the most part, the enemies of economic liberty also most stridently denounce war, often in near-pacifist terms. Yet they oppose the very economic policies most likely to encourage peace.If market critics don’t realize the obvious economic and philosophical value of markets - prosperity and freedom - they should appreciate the unintended peace dividend. Trade encourages prosperity and stability; technological innovation reduces the financial value of conquest; globalization creates economic interdependence, increasing the cost of war.Nothing is certain in life, and people are motivated by far more than economics. But it turns out that peace is good business. And capitalism is good for peace.
Good: Econ Globalization’s improvement of technology substantially improves society as a whole
Szentes, Professor Emeritus of the Corvinus University of Budapest and member of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences, 2008
(Tamas, “Globalisation and prospects of the world society,” CENTRAL EUROPEAN POLITICAL SCIENCE, Vol. 9, pp 6, http://cepsr.eu/wp-content/uploads/2013/02/ATT81762.pdf#page=9)//SG
As a matter of fact, globalisation has got more than one, single "face". It has potentially favourable and unfavourable effects alike.It brings about a challenge but also an opportunity. This follows also from the double-edge impact of its main motive forces: (a)The “revolution” in communication and information technologies substantially facilitates the expansion of economic relations between countries, internationalmigrationandtourism, and thenetworkingactivitiesof transnational companiesbuilding up and managing international production systems. It increasesthe tradability of services and also the scope of those services within the TNCs’ network, such as performed by regional headquarters, local marketing and procurement centres, accounting and financial bureaus, or even some R&D centres.Althoughspeaking about the “death of distance” is an obvious exaggeration(even in a strictly geographical sense, not to mention the “economic” and “cultural distance”9),the spread of remote employment opens new opportunities for those developing countries equipping their labour with appropriate skill and apparatus.The easier access to remote resources and markets, the reduction both of time and cost of transports, and the drastic fall in the costs of international as well as intercontinental information flows, etc., undoubtedly bring the various parts of the world closer to each other and promote the cross-border integration of production processes.The new information techniques, such as Internet, satellite and fibre-optic networks of worldwide telecommunication, etc.,make not only the costs decreasing but also the co- ordination even of those knowledge- and skill-intensive functions allocated in remote areas much easier than ever before.They facilitate also the quick responsiveness of the companies concerned and their affiliates or contract-manufacturers within the network, to any change on the demand or the supply side of the market.
Globalization results in massive economic engagements
Szentes, Professor Emeritus of the Corvinus University of Budapest and member of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences, 2008
(Tamas, “Globalisation and prospects of the world society,” CENTRAL EUROPEAN POLITICAL SCIENCE, Vol. 9, pg 7, http://cepsr.eu/wp-content/uploads/2013/02/ATT81762.pdf#page=9)//SG
The potential advantages and benefitsfrom the direct investments of TNCsand the operation of their affiliatesincludenot only • the access to additional financial resources, investmentsor reinvestments over and beyond the host country’s own financial capacity, but also •the access to foreign, more up-to-date production technologies, know-how,management and organisational skills, • international business contacts, additional information facilities andnew marketswithin the TNCs’ network,participation in their organised cross-border trade(avoiding the uncertainties of market fluctuations), •employment and in-service training opportunities for local labour and • secured supply facilities for the local “supporting” firms, contracted manufacturers and service industries, etc.
Good: Democracy Capitalism and democracy go hand in hand – economic liberty reinforces the independence of actors and their ability to defend their interests in society
Kurki, PhD @ University of Wales, Professor in International Relations Theory @ University of Wales, Aberystwyth, 13 Feb 2013
(Milja, “Politico-Economic Models of Democracy in Democracy Promotion,” International Studies Perspectives, pg 5-6)//SG
A number of authors have argued that capitalism and democracy are comple- mentary and mutually reinforcing in a “necessary” sense. Notably, it is argued that there is something inherent in the nature of capitalism that reinforces the work- ings of democracy and, specifically, liberal democracy. One key argument formany of those who see a necessary connection between capitalism and democracy has been that both democracy and capitalism arise from their shared guiding values. In short, capitalism and democracy have, as social systems, a single and shared value source, which accounts for their compatibility. For John Locke (1960),the shared value linking capitalism and democracy was the natural right to property.People are first and foremost property owners, and it is from their natural right to property that both a right to representative government and a right to free exchange of labor and goods arise from.Adam Smith (1970) also saw liberal economic capitalism as closely connected to repre- sentative government. For him, the connection between them was embedded not just in shared values but in the complementary functions of capitalism and democracy. For Smith, for the liberal market system to work effectively, there was a need for rule of law and representative institutions to guide social life.This relationship was necessary: For markets to function, there had to be some stability of expecta- tion, which is what rule of law and representative government provided. At the same time, economic liberty was seen to reinforce the independence of individual actors and hence their ability to defend their interests in society.Increased inde- pendence and wealth of the populace supports a more confident pluralist society, and crucially, these developments reduce social conflict and encourage the emer- gence of higher values and “civilized” life in societies (Berry 1997). Early nineteenth-century liberals JamesMillandJeremyBenthamalso believed in a necessary connection between capitalism and democracy, but for them, it Another viewpoint thatidentifies capitalist values as crucial to the develop- ment of democratic rights is set out in Friedrich Hayek’s (1960, 1973)and Milton Friedman’s (1962) work. Their analyses, which set the scene for the development of neoliberalism in economics and politics, state an a priori prefer- ence for liberal economic values, but also clearly argue thateconomic liberty is essential for political liberty. Friedman (2002:3) makes this argument powerfully: “By relying primarily on voluntary co-operation and private enterprise, in both economic and other activities, we can insure that the private sector is a check on the powers of the governmental sector and an effective protection of freedom of speech, or religion and thought”. Quite simply, economic liberty is a “necessary condition for political freedom” (Friedman 2002:4). Friedman, paradoxically, saw the link between economic and political freedoms to be constituted precisely by the fact that capitalist model of economic activity separates the economic from the political: “The kind of economic organization that provides economic freedom, namely competitive capitalism, also promotes political freedom because it separates economic power from political power and in this way enables the one to offset the other” (Friedman 2002:9). A variety of arguments then have been made for the necessary connection between democracy and capitalism. Whether through resort to shared values, arguments about human nature, or view of capitalism and democracy as func- tionally mutually supportive, the claim is made that capitalism is a necessary condition for democracy, and vice versa. For many, this has led to further con- clusions: For example, thatif state controls are forced on capitalism, democratic governance is endangered; that when capitalism spreads, democratic governance is made possible; and if capitalism is successful in generating economic growth, pressures toward democracy will appear (Berger, 1986; see Almond 1991:469; McFaul 2004; Mandelbaum 2007; Diamond 2008)
Democracy and free trade are directly related
Seyf, PhD in Agricultural Economics and Management, MA Economics, BA in Business Studies, and Dip Economic Development, 2012, (Ahmad, “Democracy and free market are Incompatible” The Financial Daily 5/10/12 Found on ABI Inform)//JS
There may be some differences between neoliberal advocates of democracy, but there is a common element among them that free market and democracy produce and reproduce one another. To put it differently, democracy promotes free market and free market in turn promotes democracy. Some even go as far as suggesting that without a free market economic system, there could be no democracy. Democracy strengthens free market. If a government is expected to change without violence and revolution, then, there must be a proper system in place to monitor and control and when needs be, combat the abuse of power. At the same time, if politicians could not be removed by non-violent means, what guarantee is there that they would not stay in power for ever, or, would respect private property, or would not impose heavy taxes? If any historical evidence is needed, look at Iran or Egypt. Under this situation, there would be little incentive for investment, and wealth creation and capital accumulation. Market mechanism will be distorted, and as a result there would be little or no development either. On the contrary, when there is democracy, abuse of power will be controlled, and free market system would function effectively and efficiently and the economy develops too.
At the same time, free market would also reinforce democracy and democratic institutions. It would lead to economic development and pave the way for the creation of a class of wealthy individuals who are not dependent on the state and this class would desperately need democracy to ensure that no one would abuse power.
Good: Agency Critiques of neoliberalism ignore valuable social movements and thinking—dooms progressive politics
Barnett, Faculty of Social Sciences, The Open University 10 (Clive, “PUBLICS AND MARKETS What’s wrong with Neoliberalism?”, The Handbook of Social Geography, 2010, http://www.open.ac.uk/socialsciences/emergentpublics/publications/barnett_publicsandmarkets.pdf)//AS
What’s really wrong with neoliberalism, for critics who have constructed it as a coherent object of analysis, is the unleashing of destructive pathologies through the combined withdrawal of the state and the unfettered growth of market exchange. ‘Individual freedom’ is presented as a medium of uninhibited hedonism, which if given too much free reign undermines the ascetic virtues of self-denial upon which struggles for ‘social justice’ are supposed to depend. Underwritten by simplistic moral denunciations of ‘the market’, these theories cover over a series of analytic, explanatory, and normative questions. In the case of both the Marxist narrative of neoliberalization, and the Foucauldian analysis of neoliberal governmentality, it remains unclear whether either tradition can provide adequate resources for thinking about the practical problems of democracy, rights and social justice. This is not helped by the systematic denigration in both lines of thought of ‘liberalism’, a catch-all term used with little discrimination. There is a tendency to present neoliberalism as the natural end-point or rolling-out of a longer tradition ofliberal thought – an argument only sustainable through the implicit invocation of some notion of a liberal ‘episteme’ covering all varieties and providing a core of meaning. One of the lessons drawn by diverse strands of radical political theory from the experience of twentieth-century history is that struggles for social justice can create new forms of domination and inequality. It is this that leads to a grudging appreciation of liberalism as a potential source for insight into the politics of pluralistic associational life. The cost of the careless disregard for ‘actually existing liberalisms’ is to remain blind to the diverse strands of egalitarian thought about the relationships between democracy, rights and social justice that one finds in, for example: post-Rawslian political philosophy; post-Habermasian theories of democracy, including their feminist variants; various postcolonial liberalisms; the flowering of agonistic liberalisms and theories of radical democracy; and the revival of republican theories of democracy, freedom, and justice. No doubt theorists of neoliberalism would see all this as hopelessly trapped within the ‘neoliberal frame’ of individualism, although if one takes this argument to its logical conclusion, even Marx’s critique of capitalist exploitation, dependent as it is on an ideal of selfownership, is nothing more than a variation on Lockean individual rights.
Neoliberalism is flexible and accommodating to gender and class struggles—they can coexist
Newman, Emeritus Professor, Faculty of Social Science, The Open University Visiting Professor, Social Policy, University of Bath 13-- (Janet, “Spaces of power: feminism, neoliberalism and gendered
Labour”, Social Politics 20:2, Summer 2013, http://oro.open.ac.uk/36727/2/22228FF7.pdf)//AS
Feminism, I want to suggest, was the source of emergent forms of politics and practice which in turn opened up what I term ‘prefigurative pathways’. Some such pathways were articulated into would-be hegemonic forms of rule to become a new ‘dominant’ formation. But in the process neoliberalism itself had to adapt and flex to take account of particular strands of feminism: its claims and demands, and the cultural and politics shifts it had generated. And, as Clarke and Newman (1997), Gilroy (1992, 2004), Hall et al (1978), Weeks (2009), and others show, neoliberalism also encountered other antagonisms generated through the politics of race, class, colonialism, and LGBT struggles, each of which were not containable within the confines of an exclusively British reading of history, nor support narratives of the wholesale erasure of struggle and dissent. Such struggles were often configured with traces of ‘residual’ formations that continued as effective forces into the present in ways that disrupt readings of ‘epochal’ change. his form of analysis problematises concepts of ‘after’ and ‘post’ neoliberalism referred to in the Introduction. But the argument I want to develop here is rather different. I want to propose that new orderings of the ‘dominant’ were most likely to emerge in conditions where counter projects and movements formed a ‘perverse alignment’ with neo-liberal logics. This concept is inspired by the work of the Brazilian scholar EvelinaDagnino who traced a ‘perverse confluence’ between the popular participatory project (represented in the success of struggles against the military dictatorship in Brazil) and the neo-liberal conception of a minimal state. The perversity is located in the fact that despite ‘pointing in opposite and even antagonistic directions, both projects require an active, proactive civil society’ (Dagnino, 2007: 335: see also Newman and Clarke, 2009: 139). This offers a different, but sympathetic, reading of the ‘elective affinities’ between feminism and neoliberalism referred to by Fraser. I want to use it here to suggest the significance of the different ‘perversities’ generated in the multiple spaces of power traced in the previous section.
Good: Mexico Economic liberalization and privatization streamlined the Mexican economy, improved coexistence among citizens, and improved society
Gates, Ph.D in Anthropology @ University of British Colombia, Professor of Anthropology at Simon Fraser University, 1996
(Marilyn, “The Debt Crisis and Economic Restructuring:Prospects for Mexican Agriculture,,” NEOLIBERALISM REVISITED – Economic Restructuring and Mexico's Political Future, edited by Gerardo Otero, Westview Press, pg 48-49)//SG
Differences in presidential style did, however, become apparent.Whereas the trademark of the de la Madrid administration was caution, bold and rapid reform became the dominant motif under Salinas. De la Madrid talked exten- sively about moral renovation, butSalinas engaged in a tough and comprehen- sive anticorruption campaignthat resulted in the apprehension of the notorious leaders of two of Mexico's strongest unions, a drug czar, a top fi- nancier, and other significant public figures, often political allies. De la Madrid held state agencies to austerity budgets;Salinas trimmed the government fat to the bone in many sectors, introduced significant government decentraliza- tion, streamlined economic procedures via extensive deregulation and tax re- form, and initiated a widespread privatizationdrive resulting in the sale or closure of over 800 public enterprises, even finding buyers for some of the most inefficient ones such as Aeroméxico and Teléfonos de Mexico (Teichman, Chapter 8, this volume).6 Themost dramatic changesunder President Salinaswere in the economic sphere, particularlywith respect to rapid and comprehensive measures to con- tinue the economic openingvia relaxationin the foreign investment lawand tariff reduction. These reforms were integrated within an overall program of . national economic and political modernizationexplicitly designed to "strengthen [Mexico] in the global context and improve coexistence among Mexicans . . . to create a viable economy in a strongly competitive international environment and thus to generate employment and opportunities for all . . . to forge a more just, more generous, more valuable society for each one of us, more respected in the world" (Salinas de Gortari, 1990:1, my translation). In the political do- main, Salinas envisioned "democracy consubstantial with the economic mod- ernization of our country . . . a public service that serves rather than being served by power . . . a new political culture" (Salinas de Gortari, 1990:1, my translation).Another high-profile areaduring the early part of the Salinas administrationwas the further renegotiation of the foreign debtunder the widely publicized Brady Plan. This agreement, reached in March 1990, cut Mexico's debt service Payments by $4 billion a year. Although less than was anticipated originally,it was sufficient to boost private-sector and foreign investor confidence in the economy and bring interest rates down to their lowest level since 1981. Most important, the savings appeared to give Salinas the impetus to devote attention to Mexico's chronic social problemsand to devise specific initiatives to promote the recapitalization of agriculture, the Achilles heel of the Mexican economy. The efforts of President Salinas to promote economic dynamism in agricul- ture were directed initially to attempt to eradicate the corruption fostered by the "industry of disasters" and improve the efficiency of the agricultural devel- opment agencies. Late in 1989, it was announced that BANRURAL, the rural credit bank for ejidos, would cease to employ field inspectors who had been in a prime position to initiate insurance and other frauds. At the same time, the agricultural insurance agency ANAGSA was abolished, having become notori- ous for corrupt practices as blatant as collecting indemnification for phantom crops. This agency was replaced in June 1990 by a new insurance company, AGROASEMEX,a parastatal affiliate of the Aseguradora Mexicana, which was to operate with only one-third the personnel employed by ANAGSA and without field inspectors. So far, this cleanup campaign has uncovered hundreds of major frauds at all levels, including among ejidal officers. However, petty swin- dles appear to have increased in the latest phase of the debt crisis, largely in re- sponse to massive decline in real wages to less than half of 1982 levels. With average salaries of less than $300 a month, agrarian bureaucrats often feel com- pelled, at the very least, to cheat on their gasoline allowances, to extort boxes of produce from the ejidatarios, and to rob their employers of time by padding their work sheets.
Good: LGBT Capitalism essential to LGBT rights movements
Githens, Assistant Professor Department of Leadership, Foundations, and Human Resource Education at the University of Louisville 09 (Rod P, “CAPITALISM, IDENTITY POLITICS, AND QUEERNESS CONVERGE: LGBT EMPLOYEE RESOURCE GROUPS”, New Horizons in Adult Education and Human Resource Development 23:3, Summer 2009, University of Michigan Libraries)//AS
Within HRD, many voices have called for broadening the scope of the field to include societal issues and the development of more humane and ethical workplaces (e.g., Bierema&Cseh, 2003; Bierema&D'Abundo, 2003; Fenwick, 2005; Hatcher, 2006; O'Donnell, 2007). ERGs provide one such location for this type of development. However, ERGs balance their activist agendas with the need to contribute to the organization. Corporate motivation for supporting these efforts is not necessarily altruistic and is often enabled by the capitalistic goal of improving organizational effectiveness (Gedro, 2007). Influenced by approaches that focus both on LGBT-specific identities and broader conceptions of sexuality, known as queer theory, these employee groups have continued the long tradition of advancing LGBT issues through capitalism. Through a conceptual and historical discussion, I argue that these groups resulted from the unique convergence of capitalism and two sometimes-opposing social organizing strategies: queer politics and identity politics. Although these groups exist in various forms and in multiple types of organizations, I focus on formally-recognized ERGs within for-profit corporations (for a discussion of other types of groups, see Githens& Aragon, 2007). This article’s purpose is to explore the ways in which the productive tensions between capitalism, identity politics, and queerness have manifested themselves in LGBT ERGs and created structures and activities that result in development for individuals, organizations, and societies.
Capitalism provides the vehicle for LGBT acceptance and identity
Githens, Assistant Professor Department of Leadership, Foundations, and Human Resource Education at the University of Louisville 09 (Rod P, “CAPITALISM, IDENTITY POLITICS, AND QUEERNESS CONVERGE: LGBT EMPLOYEE RESOURCE GROUPS”, New Horizons in Adult Education and Human Resource Development 23:3, Summer 2009, University of Michigan Libraries)//AS
In modern Western culture, before the creation of the concept of homosexuality in the 19th century, people who had sex with others of the same gender were merely engaging in sinful behavior (D'Emilio& Freedman, 1997). With the creation of homosexuality as anew pathologicalcondition to label those individuals, they were no longer merely regular people engaging in sinful acts, they were a distinct group of people. Shortly thereafter, the formation of formal and informal groups based on this sexual identity was a subversive effort to exert power and shift a negative attribute into a powerful collective force by taking advantage of this pathological identity (D'Emilio& Freedman, 1997; Foucault, 1978). As I explain later, the evolution of capitalism has provided the structures through which this unique identity has emerged (D'Emilio, 1993). These forces have resulted in numerous advances in the acceptance of LGBT individuals in society. However, some have argued that LGBT identity politics has reached its limits and that LGBT individuals should argue for individual liberties rather than equality as a minority group (e.g., Yoshino, 2006). Others advocate queer and universalizing approaches (rather than identity-based approaches) in which sexuality is seen as fluid and existing on a continuum (Sedgwick, 1990). They argue that such approaches are more appropriate because of the opportunity for opening productive discussions by examining the normalization of heterosexuality. Broader queer approaches have the potential to open up conversations and include a wider range of individuals. However, the adoption of more complex queer approaches has implications for how sexuality is addressed in workplace settings. Instead of seeking to create an understanding of and recognition of LGBT persons, queer approaches by 20 employee activists would seek to complicate sexuality and gender by dealing with the multifaceted approaches to “performing” gender and sexuality. I also consider the warnings of those who contend that radical deconstruction in queer theory leads to a loss of grounding that can result in immobilization due to the rejection of sexual identity as a meaningful category (e.g., Green, 2002). I explore the practical ramifications of taking such an approach and the problems surrounding the normalization of queerness by corporations.
Capitalism allows freedom of identity and rights advancements for the LGBT community
Githens, Assistant Professor Department of Leadership, Foundations, and Human Resource Education at the University of Louisville 09 (Rod P, “CAPITALISM, IDENTITY POLITICS, AND QUEERNESS CONVERGE: LGBT EMPLOYEE RESOURCE GROUPS”, New Horizons in Adult Education and Human Resource Development 23:3, Summer 2009, University of Michigan Libraries)//AS
D’Emilio(1993) argues that the rise in gay and lesbian identity in the U.S. is a direct result of the structures created by capitalism. He explains that homosexual acts and tendencies have occurred throughout history; however, the idea of being gay or homosexual is a relatively new phenomenon (also see Foucault, 1978). D’Emilio concludes that the emergence of such identities was a slow process that started in the colonial era when capitalism began replacing the widespread system of individual household production. Over decades, the number of selfsufficient households declined. These households had relied on the nuclear family (i.e., husband, wife, children) for production, but became part of a system of wage labor that deemphasized self-sufficiency. With household production, individuals needed to move into heterosexual relationships because of the central role that procreation played in living a sustainable life. Capitalism, on the other hand, allowed for selling one’s labor and purchasing goods that were produced outside of the family. This shift resulted in a steady, gradual decline in household production and a decline in the importance of procreative relationships in maintaining a decent life (as evidenced by declining birthrates). As a result, individuals with same-sex attractions were no longer compelled to enter opposite-sex relationships. Over the span of decades, people with same-sex attractions slowly started entering same-sex relationships and developing social networks that included others who also had same-sex attractions. D’Emilio (1993) explains that this gradual change and the slow emergence of gay identities culminated in World War II, which resulted in the explosion of gay identity formation. The war took thousands of men and women from around the country and placed them into samesex environments, in addition to placing those who already identified as gay into those environments. Same-sex sexual relations occurred throughout the war, and many gays and lesbians remained in large cities after the war ended, which resulted in the formation of urban 21 communities based on sexuality. Later, the Stonewall riots occurred (in 1969), which is seen as the formal beginning of the gay and lesbian liberation movement. D’Emilio explains that the structures of capitalism (e.g., movement to cities that resulted from the decline in self-sufficient households) allowed the gay and lesbian movement to form a grassroots network that was activated after the events in 1969. In the last 30 years, this network was responsible for the pressuring of corporate leaders that resulted in astounding success in changing workplace policies. Most post-World War II capitalists did not embrace gays and lesbians. In fact, there is a well-documented history of oppression by employers, especially during and after the McCarthy era (D'Emilio& Freedman, 1997). After Stonewall, activists began targeting prominent companies like AT&T, who were openly discriminatory in their hiring practices toward gays and lesbians (Raeburn, 2004a). The first LGBT ERG formed in 1978 (Raeburn, 2004a); however, it took years of work on the part of activists before most companies started adopting nondiscriminatory policies. Interestingly, corporations have been more progressive in their practices toward LGBT individuals than governmental agencies (for a discussion of federal government employment practices during the Clinton administration, see Hirsch, 2000). Many companies adopted LGBT-friendly policies before state and local nondiscrimination laws were changed to include sexual orientation.3 Most companies do not adopt these policies for purely altruistic reasons. One reason for adopting inclusive policies is to capture a larger share of what is perceived as a lucrative LGBT consumer market.4 By adopting these LGBT-friendly policies, companies often alienate other customers, particularly religious fundamentalists (for an excellent discussion of the complicated history of LGBT relations at Disney, see Truesdell, 2001). Many companies are willing to confront this risk. However, I argue that one of the most important reasons companies have adopted these policies is due to pressure by employee activists and to keep LGBT employees happy. It is important to examine the conditions that created an environment where employers sought to ensure the satisfaction of LGBT workers, while risking the loss of customers. As capitalism created the structures for the creation of gay and lesbian identities, newer forms of capitalism have also created conditions in which a substantial portion of an individual’s identity is wrapped up in work (Ciulla, 2000). In the 1950s, workplaces sought to improve productivity through enhancing human relations at work and implementing paternalistic employment practices (e.g., comprehensive pension programs, career-long employment). In the current era, these paternalistic practices have been replaced by new approaches that are designed to increase worker productivity through helping employees create meaning through their jobs (Ciulla, 2000). Today, individual identity is intertwined with work, especially for many white-collar workers. As a result of this shift, work is no longer a place individuals go to sell their labor; instead, individuals go to work to seek meaning in their lives. With this identification of the workplace as a center of personal identity, it has become essential that employers keep their workers happy inorder for workers to have meaningful careers (which leads to maximizing productivity). For a few decades, workers and employers assumed that most people would spend an entire career with one organization. Currently, most jobs are not secure and workers expect to have free choice in employment—moving from job-to-job in order to find the most meaningful and wellpaying position. Workers are no longer consumers only after work hours when shopping for goods and services. They are now consumers at work. Especially during strong economic times, workers expect to find an ideal job and they are not afraid to leave an employer to seek a better deal elsewhere. With the replacement of defined-benefit pension plans by 401(k) plans, workers have little incentive to remain with an employer if they are not satisfied. Those who advocate free choice and autonomy celebrate this consumer mentality in employment. Later, I will return to a discussion of the dangers of this consumer mentality. On the upside, this consumerism in employment has allowed LGBT employee activists to encourage change in workplaces.In contrast, politicians and government administrators have not been as eager to adopt these suggested changes (neither in government employment practices nor in employment laws).
Share with your friends: |