The 50 States can uniformly form common taxes, pool resources and pay for social services
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. 126-127)
I have argued that the states should have clear responsibility for a specific set of services, including education and other public investments needed to increase the productivity of the American economy. States are better able to experiment and adapt to the special needs and strengths of their areas. They are more apt to command citizen loyalty and participation than faraway Washington. Anyone who advocates increased reliance on states to improve public services, however, must address the question: Where will the states get the money? State governments have been struggling to meet the rising cost of public programs and have often encountered strenuous public resistance to tax increases. Budgetary stress in state capitals reached crisis proportions in the recession of 1990-92, when a large number of states were forced to cut spending and raise taxes in the face of mounting deficits. Even in good times, states face two obstacles in raising the revenue needed to provide high-quality public services; First, states have unequal resources, and the poorer ones would have trouble financing adequate services even if their tax rates were high. Second, states compete with each other. They are reluctant to let their taxes get out of line with those of other states, especially neighboring states, for fear of losing businesses, sales, or people across the state line. A new proposal that I call "common shared taxes" could mitigate both problems. A simple example would be a common sales tax shared by all the states. The tax rate would be identical in each state and would apply to the same types of sales. No one would have an incentive to shop in another state in order to avoid the tax. If the revenue were divided on the basis of state population-each state receiving the same amount per resident-poorer states would get back somewhat more than their own collections, because their per capita sales are below average. WHERE THE MONEY COMES FROM In 1990 state and local revenue totaled $740 billion-about 14 percent of GNP.! About 18 percent of state and local revenue came from the federal government. Property, sales, and income taxes accounted for most of the rest (figure 8-l). State and local funding also comes from an astonishing variety of other sources, such as lotteries, parking meters, fishing licenses, liquor store profits, water sales, bridge tolls, and university tuition.
A common tax would raise state revenue and would prevent tax payers from escaping taxation
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. Page 152)
Interest in reducing the diversity of tax systems is growing around the world as economies become more interdependent and taxpayers move more easily across borders. The countries of the European Community are making their taxes more uniform as they eliminate trade barriers among themselves. The American states, by contrast, have never made serious efforts to harmonize their taxes, although they have been part of a common market for more than 200 years. The most frequently voiced objection to the idea of common shared taxes in the United States is political infeasibility. Skeptics allege that Congress would not enact a major tax whose proceeds would be spent by other levels of government and that
states do not have the tradition of cooperation that would permit them to form an interstate compact to share one or more common taxes. Even if they cooperated to the extent of putting a common tax into operation, the rich states would certainly want to retain all the revenue generated in their jurisdiction and not share it with less affluent states. These objections may well be valid, but many policies initially labeled "politically infeasible" have eventually come to pass. The need for additional state revenue is great, even without devolution of federal functions, and states are increasingly conscious of the need to find a way of taxing growth sectors of the economy, especially services. They are also increasingly aware of the mobility of taxpayers and tax sources across borders in an increasingly interlinked national and global economy. Cooperation on common taxes might start in a small way-say with catalog sales or professional services-and then spread to a larger portion of the tax base. Acceptance of a formula for dividing revenues, such as by population, would have the appeal of simplicity, even if it involved some redistribution. Moreover, redistribution is easier to swallow if the whole revenue pie is growing, as it would be if common taxation allowed the states to tax sources that are now escaping taxation altogether by moving, or threatening to move, across borders.
A common tax will improve social services and reduce costs for businesses
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. Page 142)
States might provide higher-quality services if they shared some taxes and did not have to worry so much about losing businesses to neighboring states with lower tax rates. They would then have more incentives to compete on the basis of the excellence of their services. They would have to attract businesses and residents with good schools, parks, and transportation, rather than with tax breaks. The common taxes would also simplify the tax structure and lower the compliance costs facing companies that operate in many states, as well as reducing the enforcement costs of the tax collectors. Joint action, of course, might not look so attractive to the taxpayer who could no longer escape across the border to a low-tax state)
A corporate common tax would ensure the closing of loopholes
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. Page 145)
The federal government taxes corporate income, as do most states. Because state corporate income taxes differ widely in rate and definition of income, multistate corporations have to file different tax returns in each state in which they operate. Corporate tax accountants try to find ways of allocating the corporation's total income in a way that minimizes the tax paid. States, for their part, try to get as much as possible. Corporations allege that they are paying tax on the same income in more than one jurisdiction. The evidence, however, indicates that some corporate income escapes any taxation at the state level.14 A common shared corporate income tax would reduce compliance and enforcement costs and tax corporate income fairly and only once. The common shared state tax could be separate from the federal corporate income tax or combined with it. A single national tax shared by the federal government with the states (the German model) has some appeal.)
2NC COMMON SHARED TAXES SOLVE
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. 16-19)
This focus on federalism suggests several quite drastic proposals aimed at reenergizing the American economy and restoring confidence in the political system. Their basic theme is that the federal and state governments should divide the jobs to be done and get moving.
-The productivity agenda. The states should take charge of the primary public investment needed to increase productivity and raise incomes, especially to improve education and skill training and modernize infrastructure.
-Devolution. The federal government should eliminate most of its programs in education, housing, highways, social services, economic development, and job training.
-Common shared taxes. With federal blessing, or even the assistance of the federal government, states should strengthen their revenue systems by cooperating in collecting common taxes to be shared among them on a formula basis.
-Health care financing. The federal government should adopt a plan that will ensure basic health insurance coverage for everyone and control the increase in health costs.
-Federal budget surplus. The federal government should run a surplus in its whole budget (counting social security), thus reducing federal debt service costs and adding to the pool of saving available to finance private investment.
These proposals fit together. State responsibility for the productivity agenda would sharpen the distinction between federal and state tasks, making it easier for citizens to understand what each level of government does and to blame the right set of officials for poor performance. Devolution would take whole areas of public spending out of the federal budget, making it easier to move that budget toward surplus. More important, making clear that the devolved functions belong to the states, not the federal government, would transfer pressure for increased spending in these areas from Washington to state capitals and help keep federal deficits from recurring. The resulting fiscal pressure on states and localities would be alleviated in two ways. First, federal responsibility for health care financing, coupled with strong cost controls, would relieve states and localities of the escalating burden of medicaid and reduce the cost of other public medical care. Second, the adoption of one or more common shared taxes would improve the states' collective revenue-raising capacity. One example of a common shared tax would be a uniform state sales tax (or value-added tax) collected at the same rate on the same items and shared on the basis of population. A uniform corporation income tax, collected along with the federal income tax and shared on a formula basis, would make tax compliance simpler for multistate corporations. A common state energy tax could reduce pollution and promote conservation as well as raising revenue (see chapter 8). The idea of states sharing common taxes is a radical departure from the American tradition that each state must go it alone in levying taxes. In other federal systems, tax sharing is more usual. In Germany, for example, the central government collects most of the taxes and shares the proceeds with the Liinder (states). German taxpayers, individual and corporate, fill out only one income tax return, for both federal and state taxes. German firms pay a value-added tax whose proceeds are shared between the federal government and the states, with disproportionate shares going to the least affluent states to help equalize services. As the American economy becomes more national and international, the case for more coordination of state taxation increases. People, companies, sales, and services move with greater ease across borders. One consequence is that states and localities have to worry about keeping their tax rates from getting out of line with those of other jurisdictions. Another is that more and more companies, and even individuals, owe taxes in multiple jurisdictions. The resulting complexity is costly for both taxpayers and tax collectors. Like federal grants, common shared taxes could be designed, to improve the relative position of the least affluent states. Unlike federal grants, however, they would not cause confusion about which level of government has responsibility for particular programs or impose federal rules and guidelines on state and local authorities. To revive the American dream, citizens must find new energy and commitment to revitalize the myriad institutions that influence American life-families, businesses, schools, unions, churches, clubs, and government at all levels. They must be willing to experiment, restructure, and try new approaches to old and new problems. In the words of David Osborne and Ted Gaebler, they must even "reinvent government" by breaking out of old hierarchical patterns and empowering those closest to the problems to participate in finding solutions.6 A first step is to reexamine that peculiarly American institution, federalism. The current confusion of responsibilities between federal and state government is undermining confidence in government and impeding the implementation of policies needed to restore a healthy economy. Sorting out the roles more clearly could break the logjam, help both levels function more effectively, and improve both domestic and foreign policy.
No federal oversight is needed- interstate compact solves
Rivlin, 92- an economist, a former U.S. Cabinet official, and an expert on the budget.
(Alice Rivlin, “Reviving the American Dream”; Brookings Institute Pg. Page 147-148)
Implementing a common shared tax requires some mechanism for deciding the initial rate and the base of the tax (for example, 6 percent on retail sales except food and medicine); by whom the tax is to be collected; by what formula the revenues are to be divided; and how future changes in the rate or the base of the distribution formula are to be arrived at.
One possibility is for the federal government to enact the tax and distribute it to the states. Another is for the states-groups of contiguous states or all fifty-to work out the problems themselves by interstate compact. Still another is a federal tax credit for uniform state taxes. All approaches would have advantages and disadvantages.)
FUNDING FOR THE CP BAD
Literature does not check abuse – we live in a day where you can find information on anything – the question should be the nature and scope of the evidence. With 50 different actors context is key. Having evidence on a funding mechanism is NOT the same as having evidence that takes all 50 states into account.
Infinitely Regression – This is abusive – there is no way this is fair, or beneficial to the activity or the affirmative. There is an endless list of possible funding mechanisms the negative could choose from. They could have a different one for not only every tournament, but every debate. Pick “X” product or activity and add tax at the end and you begin to see the endless possibilities.
Turn – Fairness - This would crush competitive equity and make an already abusive cp even more so. In a world where it is impossible to win on the affirmative - the entire activity suffers. This triumphs all their increase education and ground arguments.
Not real world – All fifty states are 50 states for a reason. They have 50 different ways of doing things. The CP overlooks this with its finding mechanism.
Turn - education – in a world of a potentially constantly changing funding mechanism implemented in an unrealistic way – there is NO educational value received. We leave the debate more frustrated, not smarter.
Creates an artifical net benefit – they allow you to vote for the cp base on nothing linked to the plan – i.e. solvency or link based off the plan
Interpretation – the cp must be limited to questions of solvency or disads linked to passing the plan. The funding mechanism is neither. This better for reasons of fairness and education.
Literature does not check abuse – we live in a day where you can find information on anything – the question should be the nature and scope of the evidence. With 50 different actors context is key. Having evidence on a funding mechanism is NOT the same as having evidence that takes all 50 states into account.
This justifies intrinsicness perms - Perm_____________________________ and use the ____________________________ funding mechanism. Intrinsic perms are key to checking abusive counterplans and are justified for the reasons above.
Share with your friends: |