Part I: conceptualizing and justifying ip space 3


PART III: ALTERNATIVES TO IP REGULATION; NATIONAL AND TRANSNATIONAL ASPECTS OF GOVERNANCE



Download 0.64 Mb.
Page12/13
Date29.07.2017
Size0.64 Mb.
#24583
1   ...   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13

PART III: ALTERNATIVES TO IP REGULATION; NATIONAL AND TRANSNATIONAL ASPECTS OF GOVERNANCE




Alternatives to IP regimes




Formal Regulation



Competition Policy


  • Lametti presented competition policy as, not so much an alternative to IP regimes, but rather as an adjunct to them. Competition policy can be employed to prevent the over-extension of IP rights by intervening in particular circumstances where those rights are exercised in such a way as to restrict the competition necessary to ensure the efficient allocation of resources. Relevant question is - Does the exercise of the right in this way have anti-competitive effects?



Trebilock, “The Law and Economics of Cdn Competition Policy”


Michael Trebilock, “The Law and Economics of Cdn Competition Policy” CB II p. 323


  • IP laws and competition policy are related b/c they affect the dvlpt and diffusion of innovations

  • Traditional view is that there is inherent tension btwn them  IP rights grant monopoly and thereby stifle competition whereas competition policy seeks to foster competition and shut down monopoly.

  • Today, they are complementary instruments b/c there is growing willingness to restrict short-term competition in order to protect increased efficiency and productivity arising from innovation in the future. The challenge facing policy makers is to coordinate IP instruments and competition instruments so as to achieve efficient allocation of resources.


Three Principles which should guide competition policy with respect to IP:

  1. There should be no presumption that an IPR creates market power

  2. Competition policy should acknowledge the basic rights granted under patent (IP) law

  3. A licensing restriction should be permitted if it is not anticompetitive relative to the outcome that would result if the license were proscribed; otherwise, an evaluation of potential efficiency effects of the restriction on the pricing and diffusion of the IPR should be made.

Trebilock defines the roles of IPRs and competition policy as follows: IP law defines the rights that encourage innovation; competition policy prevents the anticompetitive transfer and use of technology while respecting the basic exclusive rights as laid out by patent law.


Trebilock suggests that the focus of competition policy wrt IPRs should be on unilateral licensing practices by a dominant firm, and in particular on exclusive restrictions which have horizontal effects.


      • Horizontal: contracts that coordinate activities among horizontal competitors in a market resulting in reduced competition

      • Vertical: Contracts that coordinate the incentives of a downstream licensee with the interests of an upstream producer or licensor.


Unilateral Licensing Practices by a Dominant Firm


  1. Tied sales and extensions of IPRs

  • Tie: supply of one product (the tying product) either on condition that the buyer also take a second product (the tied product) or on terms that induce the buyer to take the second product in addition to the first.

  • May be of two types: bundling (e.g. bundling of patents in licensing Ks) and requirements tying (buyer’s right to buy one product is tied to the obligation to buy all requirements of a 2nd product exclusively from the same seller

  • *e.g. Microsoft IE case – MS refused to license OS unless PC manufacturers agreed not to alter the OS and its interaction with the browser; also made it impossible for user to remove IE

  • *e.g. Royalty payments beyond the patent life – Cdn case in which party argued that this was an illegal attempt to extend patent rights and thus a restraint of trade; court rejected arg b/c parties agreed to it and the agreement was not unreasonable.

  • *e.g. Trademark as the tying product (Nutrasweet aspartame case) – NutraSweet tied the use of its logo and trademark to its aspartame.

  • Under Competition Act, tying is prohibited under s. 77(2) only where three requirements are met




  1. Refusal to License

Under IP law

  • Under PA and CA, compulsory licensing can be used if innovation is not being worked to an adequate degree (particularly if some licensing is in the public interest).

  • Court may construe unreasonable royalties as refusal to license where those royalties are so unreasonable that the patent could not be worked except by the patent holder. Showing of anti-competitive effects not necessary

Under competition policy

  • Courts have generally held that mere exercise of IPRs (e.g. refusal to license a TM) does not constitute an anti-competitive act. A party’s reasonable refusal to license their TM falls squarely w/in their rights.

  • Tele-Direct case (refusal to license yellow pages TM): selectivity in licensing is fundamental to the rationale behind protecting TM




  1. Resale Price Restrictions

  • s. 61 Competition Act: IPRs cannot be used directly or indirectly to attempt to influence upward or to discourage a reduction in price of the product



  1. Exclusivity Restrictions

  • here the distinction mtwn horizontal and vertical becomes most relevant (see def’ns above)

  • Restrictions motivated by horizontal effects tend to be inefficient while Ks with vertical effects tend to be efficient.

    1. Territorial Restrictions

    • Always a vertical restraint

    • Restrict the territory in which the licensee can produce and sell

    • Usually a restriction on the licensor (cannot license others in the specified territory) and the licensee (cannot operate outside the designated area)

    • Open-territory restrictions don’t protect against competition from licensees outside the territory, while closed-territory restrictions do

    • Exclusive territory restrictions can give rise to grey markets (occurs when price differential exists between two areas and marketer buys in lower price region and undercuts exclusive distributor in higher price region) [Breck’s and Heinz]

    • In EU, there is policy of exhaustion (removal of rights of IP owners to control parallel imports of legitimately mfed foreign versions of their products). This doctrine doesn’t apply in Canada.

    • Trebilock outlines a number of incentives for setting up exclusive territorial restrictions and justifications for cutting back on grey marketing:

        • Provides an incentive to the distributor to invest in GW (e.g. marketing, building product quality and reputation) without fear of free-riding. Grey-marketers free ride. If investments in GW are not protected, there will be no incentives to make them in the first place.

        • Parallel importing could frustrate the objectives of TM protection, i.e. preventing consumer confusion and protecting a firm’s goodwill

    • On the other hand,

        • grey marketing/parallel importing offers more choice and lower prices to consumers

        • Grey goods are typically of identical quality to the TM owner’s goods

    • IP Regimes such as Patent Act and Trademark Act can be used to claim infringement against parallel importation of goods embodying the IP; Competition Act can be used to challenge territorial arrangements. There have been patent and TM infringement cases but no challenges under the Competition Act.




    1. Exclusive licensing

    • The assignment of exclusive rights to the use of an IPR to a single party for a specified period of time. The exclusive transfer of IP rights is not necessarily an offence under either IP law or competition law.






    1. Exclusive dealing

    • Under an exclusive dealing K, the licensee is required not to engage in the use or sale of the technology or products of other licensors’ work.


Section 32 of the Competition Act

  • There are explicit references in the Act that ensure that conduct that goes b/y the exercise of inherent IPRs falls w/in the Act. There are specific provisions designed to deal with abuse of IPR. There are also other sections that references can be drawn to IPR abuses (ss. 45, 75, 77 as examples)

  • Section 32 allows the A-G (attorney-general) to apply to the Fed Crt of Cda (FC) for various remedial orders to address the abuse of IPRs.

  • The remedial powers of the FC are broad: revocation of the patent, declaration of the K’ual arrangement as void, imposition of compulsory L’ing

  • Provides that where the exclusive rights & privileges conferred by patents, TM, CR have been used to

    1. Limit unduly the facilities for transporting, producing, manufacturing, supplying, storing, or dealing in any article or commodity that my be subject to trade & commerce

    2. Restrain or injure unduly trade or commerce in relation to any such article or commodity

    3. Prevent, limit, or lessen unduly the manufacture or production of any such article or commodity or unre’bly enhance the price thereof

    4. Prevent or lessen unduly competition in production, manu, purchase, barter, sale, transport, or supply of any such article of commodity then the FC may:

      1. Declare void, in whole or part, any agreement, L, arrangement relating to the use of the IPR in Q

      2. Restrain any person from carrying/exercising any or all of the terms/provisions of the agreement, L, or arrangement

      3. Direct the grant of licenses under the IPR to persons on terms & conditions determined by the Crt or if the grant/other remedies is insufficient to prevent such anticompetitive use, revoke the patent

      4. Direct that registration of TM in the register of TMs be expunged or amended

      5. Direct that such other acts be done or omitted as the crt deems necessary to prevent anticompetitive use

  • Section 32 also has the reprisal that no remedial order shall be made that would be a variance w/ any treaty or arrangement respecting IPRs to which Cda is a party to.

  • Want to leave room for IPR to work, to abuse IPR you have to go beyond the bounds of what was awarded to you. Say you have an IPR and you implement it, you need to existence of IPR in your hands to be tainted.


M. Trebilcock’s Conclusion

  • Competition policy should be based on the efficiency merits of the practice as opposed to whether licensing generates too much or too little reward for the innovator’s research efforts. The basic exclusive rights provided by the patent grant should be respected at all points of the analysis.

  • IP differs from other property in its public goods nature – which leads to a different application of competition law in certain instances. Also consider the horizontal-vertical nature of the rel’ships b/t competitors w/ regard to licensing

  • In many cases the application of the law may be the same as in non-patent cases but certain criteria characteristic of innovations (ex. uncertainty & specific investments) may justify the use of restrictive practices. IP cases may get more leniency than non-IP cases when applying the same laws

  • Competition law should not attempt to take on the mandate of patent policy in encouraging innovation. Nor should patent law attempt to rule on anticompetitive practices.

  • Competition policy should work w/ patent policy to provide adequate incentives for innovators to share their discoveries w/ others when this is efficient. Patent & competition laws should be complimentary to strike a balance b/t dynamic & allocative efficiencies.




POINT: IP law and competition law are complementary. Comp law should respect rights allocated by IP law, but intervene where they are being over-extended in a manner that creates inefficiency (stifles competition?). Trebilock considers a number of situations/arrangements into which competition policy might intervene. His focus is on unilateral licensing practices by a dominant firm and in particular on those which have horizontal effects: tied sales (can only have license for patent A if buy license for patent B also); refusal to license (generally dealt with under IP law directly, i.e. compulsory licensing), resale price restrictions, exclusivity restrictions (including territorial restrictions which may lead to claims of TM infringement where another party engages in parallel importing). **Note that Trebilock outlines justifications both for enjoining gray marketing and allowing gray marketing (see highlights above). DL: IP law defines the right and competition law has an impact on the SCOPE OF THE RIGHT.



Volkswagen Canada v. Access International


Volkswagen Canada v. Access International, [2001] F.C.A., CB II p. 346
Facts:

  • Volkswagen and Audi were selling cars in Canada through their Canadian subsidiary Volkswagen Canada. Volkswagen and Audi assigned Cdn copyright in their marks to Volkswagen Canada.

  • V Canada was the only entity in Canada authorized to import V and A autos, parts and accessories.

  • Access International was an auto-parts supplier. It bought original V and A parts (marked with logo) and sold them to garages, etc. at a cheaper price. It bought these parts from a source other than V-W Canada and thus outside the authorized distribution channels in Canada for such products.

  • V-W Canada claimed that importation and sale of V and A parts and accessories infringed its CR

  • AI denied infringement and claimed that V-W Canada, by attempting to use its CR to prevent AI from importing genuine parts, was abusing the CR.

  • Access Int’l released statement of defense/counterclaim claiming that ptf’s action would unduly restrict trade. It referred to s. 32 of the Competition Act


Issue: Was VW Cda abusing its CR? Yes
Reasoning: Sharlow J.A.

  • Application of s 32 of the Competition Act: This provision cannot be used as the basis of a defence/counterclaim in CR infringement action (the act serves to permit the FC to grant remedies for certain uses of CR but only if the result of the CR use is to unduly or prevent competition). AIA relies on Eli Lilly & Co. v. Marzone Chemicals (1976), (patent infringement case) to justify the application of s. 32. The court does not accept AIA’s argument by distinguishing from Eli Lilly b/c the statutory preconditions preclude AIA from claiming a remedy for breach under s. 32. Thus, to permit AIA’s counterclaim to stand would mean that AIA would be benefiting from a statutory remedy (s. 32(2)(b)) w/o adhering to the statutory preconditions.

  • BUT: AIA’s equitable defence: in Eli Lilly, Addy J. indicated that the allegations in the statement of defence should not be struck b/c s. 31.1 of the Combines Investigation Act [now replaced by the Competition Act – s. 32] potentially afforded a defence to the infringement claim. Addy J. went on to say that plaintiffs who are seeking equitable relief must come into Crt w/ clean hands. If they are in breach of the statute – “this would constitute a more valid reason for refusing injunctive relief although the allegations might well not constitute a defence to a claim at law.” Thus VW Cda’s [CR holder’s] conduct may form a basis of a defence claim of equitable relief for infringement of CR.

  • Clean hands doctrine: An unclean hands defence can only be made out if & only if there is a sufficient connection b/t the subject-matter of the claim & the equitable relief sought. That is, there must be a relationship/connection between the wrongful conduct of the IPR holder & the IPR.

  • The assignment of the logos to VW Cda is conduct described in 32(1) of the Competition Act b/c the result of VW Cda obtaining the CR was to unduly limit or prevent competition in authentic VW & Audi parts & accessories. There is a sufficient rel’ship b/t the CR & the unclean hands defence that the equitable remedy may not be granted.

  • Allows the appeal except w/ regard to AIA’s counterclaim.




POINT: VW Canada was only entity in Canada authorized to sell VW and Audi parts, and owned Cdn CR in the marks on those products. Dft imported original parts marked with logo and sold them in Canada. Court found that VW Canada was abusing its CR. [unduly limiting or preventing comp in authentic VW & Audi parts]

S. 32 of Competition Act may be used as a defense to a claim of IP infringement (in this case CR) where the exercise of the IP right for which protection is being sought unduly limits or prevents competition. [Note that court doesn’t allow s. 32 to be used as a straight defense; rather it invokes equity and denies equitable relief (injunction) on the basis that, where the ptf is in violation of s. 32, the plaintiff “does not come to court with clean hands.”] SH: Could this have been used as a counterclaim in the Heinz case?




Domain Name Regulation


Domain Names

  • Alternative formal regulatory system set up by governments and non-profit orgs. Domain name governance is a formal structure created with blessing of gov’t. It works independently (K, voluntary panelists) but sits beside IP and is relevant to it (particularly to TM)

  • Domain names look like property: have economic value (are traded) and confer exclusive rights to use

  • Two important organizations: ICANN (U.S.) and CIRA (Canadian Internet Registration Authority). Both are non-profits that take care of registration and dispute resolution (farm out dispute resolution). Each has its own set of rules. Registrants agree to be bound by the registration policy and dispute resolution mechanisms and submit to a dispute-resolution service provider when a third party claims that (burden of proof on complainant):

  1. the registrant’s domain name is identical or confusingly similar to a TM or service mark in which the complainant has rights

  2. The registrant has no rights or legitimate interests in the domain name

  3. The registrants domain name has been registered and used in bad faith

  • Cybersquatting: individuals register domain names in violation of the rights of TM owners

  • Reverse domain name hijacking: TM owners abusively assert their TM rights to strip domain names from rightful owners.


UDRP

What constitutes bad faith?

  • Most attempts to divert custom: covers parody websites, criticism websites, business competitors. E.g. panelists have held that unofficial websites for rock bands divert custom and thus are in BF.

  • Any attempt to sell domain name back to co. with which associated

  • Typo-squatting in order to get people to hit your critical website

  • [SH: Registering the name of your competitor]

  • DL thinks this should be entirely subjective inquiry

What constitutes legitimate interests?

  • Registrant planning to use the name in connection w/ a bona fide offering of goods or services

  • Registrant is commonly known by domain name

  • Registrant is making a legit non-commercial or fair use of the domain name, w/o intent for commercial gain, to misleadingly divert customers or to tarnish the TM

  • Cannot register a domain name and sit on it

  • DL: legit use should be more objective; look to objective connection btwn rspdt and name

**Note that complainants won most of the time. Particularly where name is very popular or well known, panelists will just infer bad faith and no legitimate interests.
Significant changes in CIRA policy from the UDRP policy

  • better distinction btwn GF and legit use

  • modified burden of proof regarding legit use (strange that complainant has burden given relevant factors)

  • three-person panels except on default

  • explicit mention of other domain name decisions as possible sources of normativity

  • Cdn residence requirements

  • Allows for criticism websites, provided they mitigate “initial interest confusion” (i.e. must make it clear that your site is not the official one).



Sallen v. Corinthians


Sallen v. Corinthians (2001): Dude registered Corinthians.com (put up bible psgs) and holder of that TM in Brazil took UDRP action against him. WIPO panel found that he was a cyber-squatter and ordered him to transfer his reg’d domain name. Brought action in federal court to reverse WIPO decision. Claimed that his use of domain name was not unlawful under federal Anti-squatting Consumer Protection Act. Held: federal U.S. law can be invoked to overturn the WIPO decision. Sallen in compliance with ACPA. Intention of certain amendments = protect domain name registrants against overreaching TM owners; balance rights of TM holders with rights of Internet users to engage in protected expression online. Must enable registrants to counteract abusive behaviour by TM holders (i.e. taking proceedings under UDRP in order to strip a name from a registrant who has lawfully registered and used it). POINT: balance rights of TM holders with rights of Internet users.




Domain names  Private ordering (i.e. Ks) which extends IP rights?

  • Interaction with TM  TM owners register corresponding domain names; domain names registered as TMs (e.g. amazon.com)

  • Under dispute resolution mechanisms, where one holds a TM (particularly a popular one), corresponding domain name is pretty much automatic (i.e. panel will find another who registers it to be in BF/not a legit user)

  • BUT, unlike TM, domain names good around the world (scope of protection is INTERNATIONAL); and one can register a generic domain name (e.g. books.com or goodbooks.com) that would not be registrable under TM.

  • Thus domain name governance expands rights of TM holder! (across borders and to generics)

  • Sometimes the “Swiss Army Knife” has unintended consequences; i.e. chosen governance tool (domain name regulation) extends rights of TM owners.

  • **Note also that domain name regulation has extended international protection to CML rights of publicity (juliaroberts.com) and non-reg’d marks (passing off in civil law countries!)

Informal Regulation

Two examples of voluntary mechanisms that sit alongside IP: patent pools and creative commons


Patent Pools

Patent Pools: A Solution to the Problem of Access in Biotechnology Patents?


Patent Pools: A Solution to the Problem of Access in Biotechnology Patents?” CB II p. 380

  • Problem: patent rights can be very narrow. One patented invention may incorporate other patented inventions, such that patent-holder cannot make, use or sell w/o licenses from other patent-holders. Where there are hold-out problems wrt a critical patent (i.e. a “blocking patent”), R&D/production in a certain area may grind to a halt. Potential lack of reasonable access to technology for research and dvlpt of commercial products and for basic biological research. Effectively tragedy of the anti-commons. Too much ownership and fragmentation of ownership = under use.

  • Solution: patent pools (Note: in some situations, legislator could grant compulsory license)

  • Def’n of patent pool: agreement btwn two or more patent owners to license one or more of their patents to one another or third parties. OR, the aggregation of IPRs which are the subject of cross-licensing, whether they are transferred directly by patentee to licensee or through some medium, such as a joint venture, set up specifically to administer the patent pool.

  • Many of the early patent pools were government mandated, e.g. around WWI, two major holders of aircraft patents effectively blocked the building of any new airplanes. Gov’t forced creation of aircraft patent pool encompassing almost all aircraft mfrs in the U.S.

  • Patent pools can be beneficial, but government must shut them down if they are anti-competitive (i.e. effectively create a cartel; see criteria on page 386 CB)

  • Guidelines for approving proposed patent pools:

    • Patents in pool are valid and not expired

    • No aggregation of competitive technologies and setting single price for them

    • Independent expert should be used to determine whether patent is essential to complement technologies in the pool

    • Pool agreement must not disadvantage competitors in downstream product mkts

    • Pool participants must not collude on prices outside the scope of the pool

  • Benefits of patent pooling

    • Elimination of blocking patents or stacking licenses

    • Members and licensees of the pool can access all building blocks of given tech in one place = easier to take to mkt = facilitates rapid dvlpt of new technologies

    • Reduction of licensing transaction costs

    • Reduction of litigation (= small biz more likely to prosper)

    • Distribution of risks associated with R&D

    • Institutionalized exchange of technical info not covered by patents


General Public Licenses/Copy-Left

  • Generally used in software context

  • Software is copyright protected BUT licensed under a GPL, which allows a user to copy, distribute and/or modify the software provided that user abides by restrictions/responsibilities outlined in GPL. E.g. any improvements made to source code must be put back into public domain to be shared by all. E.g. any software you sell or pass along must also be accompanied by this general public license.


5. You are not required to accept this License, since you have not signed it. However, nothing else grants you permission to modify or distribute the Program or its derivative works. These actions are prohibited by law if you do not accept this License. Therefore, by modifying or distributing the Program (or any work based on the Program), you indicate your acceptance of this License to do so, and all its terms and conditions for copying, distributing or modifying the Program or works based on it. [SH: so conceivably, a person could do what he has a right to do under CR law anyway (fair use; take bits that are not original or that are mere ideas) and not abide by the license. BUT…these uses of the public domain depend on accessibility which is problematic in software context (b/c source code is locked up)] DL: unique features of software (dynamic; code locked up = undermines public domain aspect of CR protection) suggests that software should be protected by independent regime
6. Each time you redistribute the Program (or any work based on the Program), the recipient automatically receives a license from the original licensor to copy, distribute or modify the Program subject to these terms and conditions. You may not impose any further restrictions on the recipients' exercise of the rights granted herein. You are not responsible for enforcing compliance by third parties to this License.
CreativeCommons.org

  • Author has CR in work, but transfers that work from the private to the public domain by marking it with a (cc) rather than a ©

  • Author may attach constraints/reserve some of his rights such as (1) cannot copy, distribute, perform or produce derivative works w/o attribution; (2) can only copy, distribute, modify for non-commercial purposes; (3) must share (i.e. put into public domain) any work created from the work; (4) no derivative works.

  • Issue: can CR holders use K (licenses) to circumvent CR law (e.g. license runs longer than CR terms; license adds moral rights not found in CR leg [such as right of destination], license is tantamount to assignment of moral rights)? DL seems to suggest this is not a problem. (I’m not sure why!)

  • If we have a robust notion of fair use or fair dealing, do we really need this kind of system? Legitimate uses of works will already be allowed.


Note re GPLs and Creative Commons: they rely on the traditional CR regime and are necessary b/c int’l agreements now require that CR be granted automatically (upon creation of work). So if you don’t want to be part of CR scheme, must K out of it.



Download 0.64 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page