The United States federal government should close the United States Department of Transportation



Download 1.4 Mb.
Page6/34
Date18.10.2016
Size1.4 Mb.
#2971
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   34

Federal Workers Fail




Public workers increase taxation which kills markets and creates a cycle of destruction for the economy.


Epstein 10 (Richard A.the Peter and Kirsten Bedford Senior Fellow at the Hoover Institution, is the Laurence A. Tisch Professor of Law, New York University Law School, and a senior lecturer at the University of Chicago. His areas of expertise include constitutional law, intellectual property, and property rights., “Deregulate now” Hoover Institute, 2010 No.2 4/21/12 http://www.hoover.org/publications/hoover-digest/article/5298//Mkoo)

Tragically, the economic lesson often goes unheeded. Too many professors and students link arms with union organizers in the naive hope of extracting blood from a stone. A bankrupt state cannot increase allocations to the university. Meanwhile, affluent citizens pack their bags to move to low-tax jurisdictions; those who stay do more tax-free work at home or participate more heavily in the underground economy. It won’t work to reaffirm the deadly triumvirate that drives this misery: tax the rich, greater local control over real estate development, and special privileges for organized labor. What’s needed is to break from the past with some unimaginative but necessary resolutions in the areas of taxation, real estate, and labor. On taxation, don’t play the mug’s game of imposing ever higher marginal tax rates on ever lower amounts of income. Play it smart for the long haul: low income-tax rates (and no estate taxes) will attract into states and communities energetic individuals who would otherwise choose to live and work elsewhere. Treasure their efforts to enlarge the overall pie. Don’t resent their great wealth; remember the benefits their successes generate for their employees, customers, and suppliers. Repudiate the politics of envy for the social destruction it creates. Don’t fret about the states and communities left behind; let them adopt the same sound policies to keep people at home. Enterprise is infectious. The outcome won’t be a zero-sum game. Open markets are the rising tide that raises all ships; high taxation is the tsunami that sinks them. On real estate, change the culture so that getting permits for yourself and blocking them for everyone else is no longer the pre-eminent developer’s skill. The government can still prevent buildings from falling down and fund infrastructure through general taxation. But take a stand against letting entrenched landowners and businesses raise NIMBY (not in my backyard) politics to a fine art. Today our dysfunctional land-use processes too often build thousands of dollars and years of delay into the price of every square foot of new construction. The requirements on aesthetics and disability access should be junked, along with the crazy-quilt system of real estate exactions that asks new developments to fund improvements whose benefit largely accrues to incumbent landowners. And for heaven’s sake, learn the lesson of Kelo v. City of New London and stop using the state’s power of condemnation for the benefit of private developers.



Private workforce is more efficient – incentives and disincentives make them better


Kennedy 01 (Joseph V., “A Better Way to Regulate,” Hoover Institute, Policy Review N.109, http://www.hoover.org/publications/policy-review/article/7073//Mkoo)

Not all regulations are directed at the private sector. Many are meant to prevent abuses of agency discretion. Having created a large bureaucracy, elected officials must try to control it. Private firms know from experience that good management requires a delicate balance between supervisory control and employee initiative. Most of the knowledge that an organization possesses remains with its front-line workers. Especially in a changing environment, competitive firms are forced to give employees freedom to take advantage of this knowledge on their own initiative. On the other hand, employees quickly build up bureaucratic interests that can conflict with those of the broader organization. Thus, every business has management controls that either limit the freedom of workers or provide them with incentives that link their well-being to that of the company. In recent decades, companies have pushed profit and loss responsibility down to lower management levels while creating internal auditing departments that ensure corporate directives are followed. A key component of these controls is the careful design of performance measurements linked to pay incentives such as stock options and profit-sharing plans to reward employees according to their contribution to the overall success of the firm. The problems faced by government are more extreme. First, even without pay incentives, employees in private firms face two important checks on how they act. Their positions are subject to ongoing competition by other individuals within and outside the firm and can be terminated with relatively few formalities. In addition, if the firm ceases to be competitive, its operations will shrink and workers are likely to lose their jobs. Government employees face neither of these pressures to the same degree. Although promotions are competitive and agencies are increasingly subject to tighter budget constraints, government workers still enjoy a high degree of job security: It is extremely difficult to demote or fire poor performers. This need not be. Encouraging competition among different agencies, especially those charged with offering services to the general public, would increase the tie between job performance and job security. More important, it would increase the pressure to improve performance over time. The growing movement toward housing vouchers and charter schools reflects this trend. Just as important, statutes governing federal employment should be rewritten to allow agencies to weed out nonperformers and reward overachievers. Employment practices that treat everyone the same only encourage mediocrity. In many areas, deeper government reform will have to occur. Federal purchasing rules are exceedingly complex largely because the government is unwilling or unable to hold individual purchasers accountable for their decisions. Instead, it limits their discretion with regulations that add to the cost of the final items in an effort to reduce the scope for fraud. The fact that the federal government, an entity that holds monopsony purchasing power in many markets, is afraid that smaller suppliers will take advantage of it surely indicates the existence of a structural problem. If the government structured itself more like the purchasing departments of major manufacturing firms, which have often reduced costs by over 25 percent without any reduction in quality, the need for complex regulations would diminish and purchasing costs would fall.
Public sector workers are paid exponentially more than the average private sector employee for less aptitude.

Love and Cox, 91--Illinois-based consultants who specialize in transportation, privatization, and the economics of the public sector. (Jean and Wendell, “False Dreams and Broken Promises: The Wasteful Federal Investment in Urban Mass Transit”, 10/17, http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-162.html)//EM

Unquestionably, the major explanation of the inability of the public transit industry to contain costs has been the inflated salaries and benefits of public transit workers. Public transit employees are paid as much as twice the amount received by the average nonsupervisory worker in the United States and 65 percent more than the average U.S. worker. Although the education requirement for transit drivers is less than a high school diploma, they receive nearly 11 percent more in total compensation than do private-sector employees with four or more years of college education. The average compensation for all transit employees exceeds the average salary for U.S. employees with college degrees by more than 30 percent.(34) Public transit fringe benefits average 50 percent of employee pay--nearly double the fringe benefits of the average private-sector worker.(35) Hence, when fringe benefits are added to the equation, the average transit employee receives 70 percent more in compensation than the average U.S. employee (Figure 6).(36)





Download 1.4 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   34




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page