The United States federal government should close the United States Department of Transportation



Download 1.4 Mb.
Page8/34
Date18.10.2016
Size1.4 Mb.
#2971
1   ...   4   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   ...   34

DOT Bad – Coercion




The DOT is unconstitutional and coercive.


Bohan, 12—author of “Is America Dying?”(Patrick, “Coercion (Part II)”, The Evolution of Mediocrity, 4/6, http://pbohan.blogspot.com/2012/04/coercion-part-ii.html)//EM

It seems everything the federal government does is coercive against the states, companies, or individuals. Justice Scalia suggested that the States “got an offer they could not refuse” and they signed away their sovereignty when they signed onto to Medicaid in 1965. Scalia may be right, but even in 1965 the states had no choice but to sign up for the Medicaid program. Let’s think about it. Two amendments drastically reduced the rights or sovereignty of states well before 1965 – the 14th (adopted in 1868) and 16th amendments (adopted in 1913). The 14th amendment gave the federal government power to rule on states’ due process laws. The 16th amendment gave Congress the right to impose an income tax. Once Congress had the right to levy an income tax, they had complete power over the states. In 1965, the federal government did give the states an offer they could not refuse – take our help on Medicaid or get nothing. After all, it would have been economic and political suicide not to accept the money and instead double tax the citizens of states to help pay for health coverage for the disabled or needy. The 16th amendment has enabled the federal government to coerce states for nearly a century. The government created departments not enumerated in the federal powers of the Constitution including: HHS, Department of Education (DOE), Department of Energy (Doe), Department of Agriculture (USDA), and Department of Transportation (DOT) – to name a few. The federal government collects tax money from the individuals of each state, and if the states want to recoup this money they have to adhere to federal government power grabs for universal control over healthcare, education, energy, agriculture, or transportation. For instance, the Department of Education created a new program called “The Race to the Top”. There was 4.3 billion dollars of state funding hidden in the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 (the 862 billion dollar stimulus) for the Race to the Top. Even though The Race to the Top was not a law, the federal government coerced states to abide by their guidelines to get funding for this program. Some claim that this is not coercion because the states could just refuse the money – it is voluntary. But this is not going to happen, especially during a recession where states were already cash strapped and did not want to double tax its citizens. Besides, the government could have just as easily divided the money up evenly (population adjusted) amongst the states without any strings attached – they did not do this. Let’s face facts; the introduction of the 16th amendment made the 10th amendment moot. States are now at the mercy of the federal government. And what’s worse, the 16th amendment made this country more bureaucratic, less efficient, and more susceptible to fraud and waste. For example, the tax payers of Ohio send their tax dollars to the federal treasury which in turn, funnels the money to federal departments which in turn, funnels the money back to the states treasury which in turn, funnels the money into state departments. Things would operate much more smoothly if the states taxed their people and spent the money as they saw fit, and cut out the middle man – the federal government. This simply makes sense and is more logical because states and localities better understand their issues and problems than the federal government. To assume that education or Medicaid has the same variables in Los Angeles California as it does in Alamosa Colorado is just wrong. Some may argue that by having the federal government controlling laws and regulations for HHS, DOE, Doe, USDA, and DOT makes legislation more consistent and equally enforced amongst states. This is not even remotely true and is exactly why legislation is thousands of pages long, because bills are laced with pork, earmarks, and waivers influenced by lobbying which does the contrary, it makes laws inconsistently enforced not only amongst states, but among corporations and individuals. Just this past week Congressional Democrats were talking about cutting tax incentives for only oil companies, but not tax incentives and funding for green companies – is this a fair law equally enforced amongst corporations?

Exts – Repeal Gas Tax Solvency




Repealing the gas tax removes a critical element of government control over surface transportation.


O'Toole, 12-- senior fellow with the Cato Institute (Randal, “Transportation Agreement Seems Remote”, Cato Institute, 2/3, http://www.cato-at-liberty.org/transportation-agreement-seems-remote/)//EM

The real question is why the federal government should be involved at all in highways, urban transit, bike paths, and other surface transportation projects. State and local governments, not to mention private transportation companies, are more likely to make wise transportation investments and less likely to be swayed by pork barrel. Congress should simply eliminate the federal gas tax or, as some have proposed, allow states to opt out of federal programs by raising their gas taxes by the amount of the federal 18.3-cent-per-gallon tax.


Gas Tax Bad – Econ




Gas tax distorts the economy.


Taylor and Van Doren 07 – a writer among the most widely cited and influential critics of federal energy and environmental policy in the nation and an editor of the quarterly journal Regulation and an expert in the regulation of housing, land, energy, the environment, transportation, and labor (Jerry and Peter, “Don’t Increase Federal Gasoline Taxes—Abolish Them,” Cato Institute, 8/7/07, http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-598.pdf, MMarcus)

However, academic researchers—even those who support increasing the gasoline tax—have several reservations about the double-dividend claim. First, while it’s true that a gasoline tax will not change behavior very much in gasoline markets, they impose significant distortions in other markets. For instance, a gasoline tax will reduce after-tax wages in precisely the same way as a direct tax on wages. Hence, a gasoline tax will introduce distortions in the labor market. It will also create distortions in other commodity markets by reducing demand for some goods while increasing the demand for others. Those distortions are at least as large as the distortions introduced by other forms of labor taxation, and they tend to “exacerbate, rather than alleviate, preexisting tax distortions—even if revenues are employed to cut preexisting distortionary taxes.” But for reasons that are partially illustrated above, a gasoline tax (and a tax on virtually any other commodity, for that matter) is implicitly a tax on labor, and taxing labor creates less welfare loss than taxing capital. So even if a gasoline tax hike leads to welfare losses in labor and other commodity markets, if the revenues associated with the tax were used to cut taxes on capital, it is possible that the welfare gains associated with the capital tax reductions would exceed the welfare losses associated with increasing the gasoline tax. Despite this theoretical escape hatch, the gasoline market offers too narrow a tax base to substitute in any substantial way for taxes on capital. To be revenue neutral, the gasoline tax would have to be too high. And once the tax becomes high enough, behavior will change (motorists will switch from gasoline to some other fuel—like ethanol), and behavior change implies welfare losses. Accordingly, the efficiency gains that might result from a tax swap will not offset the efficiency losses caused by the gasoline tax increase. There are two other practical complications. First, replacing income with gasoline taxes decreases the efficiency of revenue collection because it is cheaper to collect a given amount of revenue from a broad tax base relative to a narrower tax base. Second, the “double dividend” can only occur if the revenues from the gasoline tax are used to offset cuts in capital taxes. If the revenues are rebated to lower-income Americans to offset the regressivity of the tax swap—which would almost certainly happen to some extent in the current political climate—that would reduce the revenues available to “buy” cuts in capital taxes and, thus, further reduce or eliminate the efficiency gains that result from the tax swap. So while replacing capital taxes with labor (consumption) taxes is welfare-improving, the gains associated with that switch cannot be secured absent generalized tax reform across all sectors of the economy. As economist Stephen Smith observed after surveying the literature: Ecotaxes are likely to involve distortionary costs at least as high as those involved in raising equivalent revenues through existing taxes. If the question is posed whether we would choose to use energy taxes, in preference for existing taxes on labour and other bases, in the absence of any environmental benefits, then the answer is almost certainly that we would not. Energy taxes would be likely to involve just as much distortion of the labour market as income taxes, and at the same time distort the commodity market. Only if there are expected to be environmental gains can the use of environmental taxes be justified, and the case for ecotax reform must be made primarily on the basis of the environmental gains that would result. First- vs. Second- vs. Third-Best Policy Are gasoline taxes worth embracing as a “second-best” policy, given the widespread belief that “first-best” remedies, such as direct taxation of the externalities in question, are off the table? We don’t think so. First, as a factual matter, it’s unclear whether alleged first-best remedies such as tailpipe emission taxes and road use charges are truly more difficult to pass in a legislature than fuel tax increases. Energy taxes, after all, are among the most politically unpopular taxes in America, as President Bill Clinton discovered when he attempted to impose a Btu tax during the first year of his presidency. Pollution taxes, on the other hand, are somewhat more “virtuous” in the public’s mind, and highway tolls are increasingly common. If one posits that gasoline taxes are unpopular because they are visible, unavoidable, and imposed on a commodity for which demand is relatively unaffected by price, then pollution taxes and road-use charges would likely prove no more unpopular than gasoline taxes. Second, economists who argue for increased gasoline taxes rarely concede (to non-economists, anyway) that those taxes are deeply problematic and only worth embracing because better policies are presumably off the table. Instead, the case for higher gasoline taxes is usually offered to the public with a great deal of intellectual bravado that almost always overstates the ability of gasoline taxes to solve identified problems. We believe that economists should argue for first-best policies and let the political chips fall where they may. After all, if academics (who don’t have to worry about winning popularity contests at the ballot box) don’t make the case for politically unpopular first-best economic policies, who will? Abandoning the case for ideal policy in the public realm because it may prove unpopular implicitly assumes that good arguments do not persuade. It also requires economists to make judgments about what is politically feasible and what is not, and economists have no particular expertise in that matter. Third, it’s unclear whether gasoline taxes even qualify as a “second-best” means of addressing air pollution or road congestion. That’s because the difference between the upper- and lower-bound externality cost estimates are larger than the marginal gains promised by intervention. Hence, raising the gasoline tax too high could well make prices even less, not more, reflective of total costs. The only way to hedge against that risk is to support gasoline tax increases that fall within the lower bound of the aggregated externality estimates, but that would produce correspondingly little efficiency gain even in theory. As economist Stephen Smith points out: It is perhaps an over-generalization to suggest that environmental taxes should be large, or not imposed at all. However, the costs of complexity and the risk that minor environmental taxes will simply be ignored should both caution against too much environmental fine-tuning of the fiscal system. That’s particularly the case given that small, incremental tax increases do not guarantee only small, incremental welfare losses when the preexisting tax system is inefficient. Relatively small carbon taxes, for example, yield disproportionately large gross costs in theoretical simulations replicating the existing tax system. Fourth, and most important, even if a gasoline tax increase were able to perfectly price gasoline’s externalities, that would not necessarily lead to greater efficiency. In fact, the economy might become less efficient if gasoline prices are corrected in isolation of other prices. Transportation economists, including Mark Delucchi, a research scientist at the Institute of Transportation Studies at the University of California, and Clifford Winston at the Brookings Institution, have demonstrated that if all inefficiencies in transportation markets were corrected, there would be more, not less, automobile use than at present because mass transit “prices” (user charges) are even more distorted than the price of automobile travel. Hence, a perfect correction of gasoline externalities would likely make the economy less, not more, efficient to the extent that even more inefficient transit use increased.



Download 1.4 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   4   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   ...   34




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page