What are mhk technologies?



Download 0.89 Mb.
Page10/27
Date05.08.2017
Size0.89 Mb.
#26346
1   ...   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   ...   27

Economy Advantage



Economy Advantage

Two Internal Links:

A. Jobs - MHK technologies create jobs. As the technologies expand domestic education and international workers will fill any personnel gap


Chad Augustine, et al., ‘12, National Renewable Energy Laboratory, Renewable Electricity Futures Study, Volume 2: Renewable Electricity Generation and Storage Technologies, http://www.nrel.gov/analysis/re_futures/, Accessed 4/27/2014

Jobs in MHK technologies include: design, development, manufacturing, project development, deployment, shoreline development, port logistics, O&M, and recovery. Many of these jobs are engineering jobs for the design and project development stages, while the manufacturing, O&M, and recovery stages of projects are primarily technicians and skilled labor jobs. EPRI estimated that a 100-MW wave power plant provides approximately 24 permanent local jobs during the operational phase of the power plant. In this industry, deployment and recovery will require experienced personnel with offshore construction expertise. Currently, educational institutions with curricula relevant to MHK technologies are limited. As the technology begins to mature, national and local workforce development and training programs would improve the supply and skill of U.S. workers for the domestic ocean energy industry. More than likely, a successful MHK industry will be international in nature with a global workforce much like the oil and gas industry today. There is no standardized method for estimating current or future personnel requirements. Because the U.S. MHK industry is just beginning, the employment requirements are particularly difficult to estimate. Therefore, no estimate is provided.

US leadership in clean energy, specifically from water power, is key to the economy & jobs


US DOE 13 (United States Dept. of Energy, Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, Water Power Program. “Water Power for a Clean Energy Future” p. 2 Published April 2013, Accessed 23-6-14)

Building a Clean Energy Economy Leading the world in clean energy is critical to strengthening the American economy. Targeted investments in clean energy research and development jumpstart private sector innovation critical to our long-term economic growth, energy security, and international competitiveness. The U.S. Department of Energy (DOE) Water Power Program (the Program) is strengthening the nation’s global position by funding cutting-edge research to produce the next generation of hydropower and marine and hydrokinetic (MHK) technologies, and by accelerating the development of markets for those technologies. Currently, the hydropower industry employs 200,000–300,000 workers in the United States, making it not only the longest-running, but also the largest renewable electricity production workforce in the nation. However, there has been a lack of consistent hydropower educational programs in the United States. In an effort to increase our nation’s knowledge and skills in this area, the Program has sponsored new graduate research fellowships to train the next generation of hydropower specialists and engineers. The newly emerging MHK industry holds tremendous potential for job growth as MHK technologies progress towards commercial readiness. The Program invests in fellowships that fund graduate-level training and sends U.S. researchers to advanced European research facilities to establish partnerships, boost innovation, and facilitate knowledge sharing. By capitalizing on water power’s significant potential for sustainable growth, the United States can add thousands of clean energy jobs while building a sustainable, renewable energy future.


B. Competitiveness

Federal investment in MHK technologies stimulate billions from the private sector and revitalize U.S. manufacturing, boosting competitiveness


Strategic Marketing Innovations 14

Strategic Marketing Innovations (SMI), March 24, 2014, “The U.S. MHK Industry Request for the DOE Water Power Program,” Fiscal Year 2015 Energy and Water Development Appropriations, http://www.strategicmi.com/press/FY15_Request_for_MHK_ EW_Approps_FINAL_3.21.14.pdf, Accessed 4/28/2014



Development of a substantial marine hydrokinetic industry in the U.S. could drive billions of dollars of investment in heavy industrial and maritime sectors, as well as in advanced electrical systems and materials common to many renewable technologies. Federal investments would stimulate private funds in the construction, manufacturing, engineering, and environmental science sectors. The further development of each industry has the potential to employ a substantial skilled workforce. The U.S. MHK industry’s first technical roadmap, developed in 2011, details a vision to establish a commercially viable U.S. MHK renewable energy industry, supported by a robust domestic supply chain, competing on a level playing field with other energy sources, and serving domestic and international marketplaces. It calls for an operational U.S. MHK renewable energy capacity of at least 15 GW deployed by 2030. The achievement of these goals would support the creation of approximately 36,000 direct and indirect jobs across the country for fabrication, installation, operations and maintenance of MHK devices.

The Carbon Trust recently predicted that the British marine energy sector could be worth £76 billion to the U.K. economy and support 68,000 jobs by 2050. It predicted that Britain could capture almost a quarter of the global wave and tidal power market if it builds on its existing technology development leadership position. The majority of the jobs would be a result of the growing export markets into countries that have powerful waves and/or tidal currents. The study, the most in-depth of its kind, found that total marine energy capacity could reach 27.5 GW in the U.K. by 2050, enough to supply more than a fifth of current electricity demand. Marine renewable energy has the potential to become a major source of electricity for the United States, and its growth could be substantially supported through increased and focused funding for the DOE Water Power Program. Federal commitment to creating a robust U.S. marine renewables industry will advance our national economic goals by creating high-quality employment in coastal communities, long-term production in shipyards, development of fleets of vessels for deployment and servicing, and strengthening the thousands of businesses that make up the U.S. industrial supply chain. The establishment and nurturing of a U.S.-based marine renewable industry would secure our nation’s place in developing offshore renewable energy systems, thereby ensuring that the United States is an exporter, not an importer, of these technologies.


Low competitiveness rates threaten US economic leadership


Porter and Rivkin 12

Bishop William Lawrence University Professor ** Bruce V. Rauner Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School



(Michael E. Porter, Bishop William Lawrence University Professor, and Jan W. Rivkin, Bruce V. Rauner Professor of Business Administration at Harvard Business School, March 2012, “The Looming Challenge to US Competitiveness” http://www.wedc.wa.gov/Download%20files/HBR_LoomingCompetiveness.pdf) Accessed 6/26

The American economy is clearly struggling to recover from a recession of unusual depth and duration, as we are reminded nearly every day. But the United States also faces a less visible but more fundamental challenge: a series of underlying structural changes that could permanently impair America’s ability to maintain, much less raise, the living standards of its citizens. If government and business leaders react only to the downturn and fail to confront America’s deeper challenge, they will revive an economy with weak long-term prospects. During the past year, we have examined U.S. competitiveness with the help of a diverse group of scholars, business leaders from around the world, and the first-ever comprehensive survey of Harvard Business School alumni. Our research suggests that the U.S. faces serious challenges. Too often, America’s leaders, in government and business, have acted in ways that neutralize the country’s many strengths. However, the decline of U.S. competitiveness is far from inevitable. The United States remains the world’s most productive large economy and its largest market for sophisticated goods and services, which stimulates innovation and acts as a magnet for investment. To restore its competitiveness, America needs a long-term strategy. This will require numerous policy changes by government, which may seem unlikely with Washington gridlocked. However, many of the crucial steps can and must be carried out by states and regions, where many of the key drivers of competitiveness reside. More important, business leaders can and must play a far more proactive role in transforming competition and investing in local communities rather than being passive victims of public policy or hostages of misguided shareholders. What Is Competitiveness? America cannot address its economic prospects without a clear understanding of what we mean by competitiveness and how it shapes U.S. prosperity. The concept is widely misunderstood, with dangerous consequences for political discourse, policy, and corporate choices that are all too evident today. The United States is a competitive location to the extent that companies operating in the U.S. are able to compete successfully in the global economy while supporting high and rising living standards for the average American. (We thank Richard Vietor and Matthew Weinzierl for helping to articulate this definition.) A competitive location produces prosperity for both companies and citizens. Lower American wages do not boost U.S. competitiveness. Neither does a cheaper dollar. A weakened currency makes imports more expensive and discounts the price of American exports—in essence, it constitutes a national pay cut. Some steps that reduce firms’ short-term costs, then, actually work against the true competitiveness of the United States. Whether a nation is competitive hinges instead on its long-run productivity—that is, the value of goods and services produced per unit of human, capital, and natural resources. Only by improving their ability to transform inputs into valuable products and services can companies in a country prosper while supporting rising wages for citizens. Increasing productivity over the long run should be the central goal of economic policy. This requires a business environment that supports continual innovation in products, processes, and management. Boosting productivity over the short run by firing workers, as many U.S. firms did at the onset of the Great Recession in 2008, is a reflection not of competitiveness but of weakness. An economy in which many working-age citizens cannot find or do not even seek jobs may appear to enjoy high productivity in the short run, but in fact it has underlying competitiveness problems. It is a nation’s ability to generate high output per employable person—not per currently employed person—that reveals its true competitiveness. Improving competitiveness is not the same as creating jobs. Policy makers can stimulate employment in the short run by artificially boosting demand in labor-intensive local industries not exposed to international competition, such as construction. Creating jobs without improving productivity, however, will not result in sustainable employment that raises the nation’s standard of living. Rather than defining the sole goal as job creation, the U.S. must focus on becoming a more productive location, which will generate high-wage employment growth in America, attract foreign investment, and fuel sustainable growth in demand for local goods and services. Government efforts to stimulate demand are also different from improving competitiveness. Governments commonly play an important role by temporarily increasing outlays to soften the impact of recessions. Such moves may hold up living standards and company performance in the short run, but they typically don’t improve the fundamental drivers of productivity and therefore cannot improve living standards and company performance in the long run. American competitiveness is important not only for firms based or founded in the U.S. but also for foreign firms that operate in the country. Foreign firms contribute to U.S. prosperity if they bring productive activities to the U.S. that provide jobs at attractive wages. U.S. affiliates of foreign firms accounted for nearly 5% of U.S. private employment in 2009. Competitiveness is not a zero-sum game, in which one country can advance only if others lose. Long-term productivity—and, along with it, living standards—can improve in many countries. Global competition is not a fight for a fixed pool of demand; huge needs for improving living standards are waiting to be met around the world. Productivity improvements in one country create new demand for goods and services that firms in other countries can pursue. Greater productivity in, say, India can lead to higher wages and profits there, boosting demand for pharmaceuticals from New Jersey and software from Silicon Valley. Spreading innovation and productivity improvement allows global prosperity to grow. Because the global economy is not a zero-sum game, the decline of American competitiveness is a problem not only for the U.S. The global economy will be diminished if its largest national economy is weak, ceases to be an engine of innovation, and loses its influence in shaping a fair and open global trading system. Does the U.S. Have a Competitiveness Problem? It would be easy to blame America’s current economic challenges on the severe cyclical downturn we have experienced. Economic policy could then focus solely on measures to spur recovery, as it has, overwhelmingly, in the last three years. To support the interpretation that America’s problems are cyclical, not structural, one could point to the facts that labor productivity has held up in America and corporate profits hit record highs in 2010. Unfortunately, that snapshot masks deeper signs of an incipient competitiveness problem—one that began before the Great Recession and in some ways contributed to it. The problem shows up in a range of economic performance measures as well as in the trajectories of the underlying factors that drive competitiveness. Productivity. America’s long-run rate of growth in labor productivity was strong relative to that of other advanced economies in the late 1990s and early 2000s, but it began to trail off before the financial crisis. Productivity has been sustained since the crisis largely by rising unemployment and falling workforce participation, ominous signs for U.S. competitiveness. Job creation. Even more unsettling is the country’s job-creation picture. Long-term growth in private-sector employment has dipped to historically low levels, a trend that started well before the Great Recession. (See the exhibit “Disappearing Job Growth.”) In industries exposed to international competition, job growth has virtually stopped. Wages. American wages have been under pressure for more than a decade. In 2007, before the downturn, U.S. median household income stood below 1999 levels in real terms—and has fallen even more since. In the two decades prior to 2007, median income grew, but at an anemic annual rate of just 0.5%. Most affected have been middle- and lower-income workers, many of whom are more exposed to international competition today than ever before. International trade and investment. The U.S. remains the world’s largest recipient of foreign direct investment; however, growth in inbound FDI slowed in recent years to rates lower than those of many other large advanced economies. And although U.S. exports rose during the past decade, America’s share of world exports has declined substantially and in virtually all areas. Notably, Germany saw robust export share gains during the same period in many industry clusters, including some of its largest. Outlook of managers. While the data are troubling, even more worrisome is the picture painted by managers on the front lines of international competition. We recently surveyed nearly 10,000 Harvard Business School alumni to assess the trajectory of the U.S. along the two dimensions that define competitiveness: the ability of U.S.-based firms to compete successfully in the global marketplace and the ability of firms in the U.S. to support high and rising living standards in America. The vast majority of respondents, 71%, foresaw a decline in U.S. competitiveness in the coming years. Respondents also reported that when the U.S. competes with other countries to host business activities, it loses two-thirds of the time. Cracks in the Foundation This erosion reflects troubling trends in many of the factors that underpin U.S. competitiveness. This set of factors, as identified in the work of Michael Porter, Mercedes Delgado, Christian Ketels, and Scott Stern, includes macro and micro components. From a macro perspective, a competitive nation requires sound monetary and fiscal policies (such as manageable government debt levels), strong human development (good health care and K–12 education systems), and effective political institutions (rule of law and effective law-making bodies). Macro foundations create the potential for long-term productivity, but actual productivity depends on the microeconomic conditions that affect business itself. A competitive nation exhibits a sound business environment (including modern transport and communications infrastructure, high-quality research institutions, streamlined regulation, sophisticated local consumers, and effective capital markets) as well as strong clusters of firms and supporting institutions in particular fields, such as information technology in Silicon Valley and energy in Houston. Competitive nations develop companies that adopt advanced operating and management practices. In a large country like the U.S., many of the most important drivers of competitiveness rest at the regional and local levels, not the national level. Though federal policies surely matter, microeconomic drivers tied to regions—such as roads, universities, pools of talent, and cluster specialization—are crucial. Assessing the U.S. through this lens, we see significant cracks in its economic foundations, with particularly troubling deterioration in macro competitiveness. Problems include levels of government debt not seen since World War II; health care and primary education systems whose results are neither world-class nor reflective of the large sums spent on them; and a polarized and often paralyzed political system (especially at the federal level) that makes decisions only when facing a crisis. In micro competitiveness, eroding skills in the workplace, inadequate physical infrastructure, and rising regulatory complexity increasingly offset traditional strengths such as innovation and entrepreneurship. Our HBS alumni survey provided an original and timely assessment of overall competitiveness and the strengths and weaknesses of the U.S. The findings were sobering. (See the chart “Evaluating the U.S. Business Environment,” in the article "Choosing the United States," HBR March 2012.) Respondents perceived the United States as already weak and in decline with respect to a range of important factors: the complexity of the national tax code, the effectiveness of its political system, basic education, macroeconomic policies, and regulation. Some current American strengths, such as logistics and communications infrastructure and workforce skill levels, were seen as declining. America’s unique strengths in entrepreneurship, higher education, and management quality were intact, but these strengths must overcome growing weaknesses in many other areas. Nearly two-thirds of survey respondents said that the U.S. business environment is falling behind that of emerging economies, while just 8% said that the U.S. is pulling ahead. Overall, the picture that emerges is an American economy that has some crucial strengths but is weakening, with problems especially visible in macro factors. How Did America Get Here? To address America’s competitiveness problem, we must first understand the intricate and intertwined roots of the current predicament. They stem from changes in the world economy as well as failures within America itself. Increasing global options. America’s troubles trace back, ironically, to the triumph of Western capitalism over traditional communism in the 1980s. Scores of countries that previously had closed economies, weak property rights, rampant corruption, unstable governments, and decrepit physical infrastructure quickly opened for business. Many of them pursued ambitious economic strategies to boost macro and micro competitiveness. Growing prosperity turned these countries into desirable markets, attracting foreign investment. At the same time, technological improvements in communication, logistics, and IT made it possible to integrate more and more countries into global supply chains. Today it is feasible, and often profitable, to do business from anywhere to anywhere. In 1990, the 20 U.S.-headquartered companies with the largest asset bases outside the U.S. had 33% of their total assets abroad; today that figure is 58%. Whereas “multinational” used to evoke an image of a large, established corporation, today we see start-ups with global reach. As emerging economies have developed, the activities conducted there have shifted from the labor-intensive and low-tech to the capital- and knowledgeintensive. To a large extent, the proliferation of possible locations for company activities boosts global prosperity, allowing more effective specialization of resources and wider diffusion of innovation. This “rise of the rest” is potentially great news for the American economy, as prosperous emerging economies can be growth markets for U.S.-made goods, allies in supporting free and fair trade, and sources of innovation. However, as companies have become increasingly global, their connections to the communities where they operate, in America or elsewhere, have weakened. Shortened time horizons in business and government. Even as managers’ geographic horizons have broadened, their time horizons appear to have shortened. Shareholder activism, stock-based incentives, and declining managerial tenure surely injected new, needed discipline into American business and had some positive effects. However, financial markets and executive compensation practices that reward quick fixes and focus attention on “this quarter’s numbers” can tempt managers to move business activities to whatever location offers the best deal today rather than make the sustained, location-specific investments required to boost long-run productivity. Of particular concern are declining investments in America in a skilled workforce, R&D and advanced manufacturing capabilities, local supplier networks, and local educational institutions— all needed to fuel productivity. The path of least resistance—and short-term gain—is to move, not improve. In government, time horizons have also shortened. Leaders focus on the news cycle and the next election, not policies needed to strengthen America for the long term. Middle-class pressures, inequality, and unsustainable promises. Broadened geographic horizons and shortened time horizons challenge the U.S. to redeploy workers and boost their productivity as firms shift their locations. In principle, America can be better off when a low-value-added manufacturing task is moved from the Midwest to Brazil and Brazil’s growth then creates demand for high-value-added U.S. products. But what becomes of the laidoff manufacturing worker in the Midwest, especially when America’s competitive fundamentals are eroding? The resulting pressures have fallen especially on middle-class workers in the sectors of the U.S. economy that face direct global competition. These “traded sectors” have seen virtually no job growth since 1990. Also, the long- standing link between wages and worker productivity has broken. (See the exhibit “The Gap Between Productivity and Wages,” in the article "A Jobs Compact for America's Future," HBR March 2012.) Since the 1980s, U.S. wages have risen more slowly than productivity—they are now influenced by how American workers stack up against lower-paid workers elsewhere. It is not surprising, then, that lower- and middle-tier household incomes have stagnated. At the upper end of the skill and income distribution, globalization has opened opportunities for individuals with unique talents to prosper on a global scale. At least partly as a result, compensation of highly skilled professionals and upper management has raced far ahead of that of average workers, and income has become more concentrated in the upper half of 1% of earners. (See the exhibits “Incomes Are Stagnant” and “Except Among Top Earners.”) How might society cope with these pressures on the middle class? The right response includes redoubling the human and technological investments required to make American workers highly productive. Instead, starting in the 1990s, America masked the problem of stagnating incomes in the middle class in several ways. First, there was a massive extension of credit, especially to buy homes and monetize home equity. This approach contributed to the housing and consumption boom but also the bust that culminated in the financial crisis of 2008–2009. Second, as the middle and lower classes were squeezed, the federal government expanded health care benefits, with severe fiscal consequences. Third, as manufacturing and other private-sector jobs disappeared, government employment expanded. From 1990 to 2010, the only major sectors of the U.S. economy that added more jobs than public administration were education and health services (which in fact include many government-funded employees) and professional and business services. Meanwhile, effective federal tax rates dropped, especially after 2001. Hobbled government. Reductions in tax receipts, the stimulus spending necessitated by the financial crisis, and the rapid growth in health care outlays have conspired with other factors (two costly wars, a dysfunctional tax code that limits government revenue, the aging of the population) to leave the U.S. federal and state governments with soaring deficits and debts. Consequently, government in the U.S. increasingly lacks the resources to invest in the building blocks of long-run productivity. Traditionally, governments have taken the lead in providing services and assets that pay off for society but offer low returns for any one company or individual. They usually play a central role in funding education and training, infrastructure such as highways, and R&D. In the U.S., however, such spending has been shrinking as a portion of total federal spending over the past few decades (though stimulus spending in 2010 provided an uptick). Federal and state budgets have shifted from investing in the future toward paying for the past. Rebalancing the portfolio of government expenditures toward the future would be difficult in the most cooperative of political environments. Yet with the pressure on the middle class, we have seen the fraying of the center in U.S. politics. The current environment is among the most polarized in memory. In taking increasingly short-term views, politicians have made the business environment even more complicated and now seem willing to pit rich against poor and to court economic disaster in order to advance their agendas. Witness, for instance, the brinksmanship that led the federal government to the edge of default in the summer of 2011 and triggered an historic downgrading of U.S. debt. The resulting uncertainty has made businesses hesitant to invest in America. Vicious and virtuous cycles. The dynamics described here have reinforced one another in dangerous ways. For instance, inadequate investment in public goods makes the U.S. a less attractive place to do business, encouraging firms to invest abroad. The migration of business activity out of the U.S. and the accompanying loss of tax revenue make it harder for the government to invest adequately in public goods. As corporations relocate jobs and earn record profits while American wages stagnate, business as an institution faces rising skepticism in society. Politicians then find it harder to enact policies that support business in America, making it even more likely that firms will move elsewhere. In contrast, China has tapped virtuous cycles. Given its policies and sheer size, it has become a serious challenge for the United States. China has used surpluses to fund productivity-improving investments that add to surpluses; its growing domestic market attracts multinational investments, which in turn boost domestic wages and spending power; and so on. China’s economic strategy plays off the short-term focus of multinationals. To gain access to the Chinese market, for instance, some U.S. executives have been surprisingly willing to share technological insights with Chinese partners who may subsequently become able rivals. At the same time, China is believed by many to have weakened its currency artificially, failed to protect intellectual property rights, and distorted markets through state-owned companies and in other ways. We do not view Chinese economic policies as sustainable or legitimate, but the country certainly has a strategy. In contrast, America lacks a coherent strategy, and as domestic difficulties have grown, the U.S. has withdrawn from leadership in advancing the global trading and investment system. More than any single sign of loss of competitiveness, it is these reinforcing spirals, and our inability to break them, that make us worry about America’s economic future. A Call for Action, Not Despair We have painted an ominous picture of U.S. competitiveness. Yet we remain fundamentally optimistic about America’s economic future because the United States retains profound strengths that are very difficult to replicate. America’s system of higher education and its entrepreneurial community continue to be the world’s most powerful engine of innovation, on which productivity growth ultimately depends. The U.S. has an open, democratic society and a system of rewarding merit that attract much of the world’s best talent. America’s sophisticated markets and institutions foster intense rivalry, spurring companies to discover new routes to productivity. America’s firms are among the most ably managed in the world, and its capital markets remain the most vibrant despite the financial crisis. American society is more prone, without sentiment, to let more productive firms and institutions drive out less productive ones, making the economy as a whole remarkably dynamic and resilient. In many ways, the core of the U.S. economy remains strong. None of the dynamics we have described are inevitable. Nor are they dictated by unstoppable forces of nature or demographic trends. Rather, America’s situation is the result of choices, and lack of choices, by policy makers and managers. The steps to reverse the loss of competitiveness are feasible, though they will require a new focus on facing reality and acting in the common interest.

Despite a small decline in influence, the U.S. is still the engine of global growth


Kennedy and Kolet April 11, ‘14, Simon Kennedy and Ilan Kolet, Staff Writers, “U.S. Global Growth Engine Putt-Putts Instead of Purring: Economy,” Bloomberg News, http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-04-11/u-s-as-global-growth-engine-putt-putts-instead-of-purring.html, Accessed 4/14/2014

The U.S. is resuming its role as an engine of global growth, this time one that just putt-putts along instead of purring. As the International Monetary Fund declares the strengthening U.S. economy is providing a “major impulse” to the world, economists are questioning just how powerful it will prove to be. The U.S. contribution to global expansion from 2014 to 2019 will likely average about two-thirds that of the quarter-century before the recession started in 2007, according to data compiled by Bloomberg based on IMF projections. “The U.S. is still the most important engine of global growth although perhaps not as much as it once was,” said Mark Zandi, chief economist of Moody’s Analytics Inc. in West Chester, Pennsylvania.

Growth key to prevent war


Royal 10 — Jedidiah Royal, Director of Cooperative Threat Reduction at the U.S. Department of Defense, M.Phil. Candidate at the University of New South Wales, 2010 (“Economic Integration, Economic Signalling and the Problem of Economic Crises,” Economics of War and Peace: Economic, Legal and Political Perspectives, Edited by Ben Goldsmith and Jurgen Brauer, Published by Emerald Group Publishing, ISBN 0857240048, p. 213-215)

Less intuitive is how periods of economic decline may increase the likelihood of external conflict. Political science literature has contributed a moderate degree of attention to the impact of economic decline and the security and defence behaviour of interdependent states. Research in this vein has been considered at systemic, dyadic and national levels. Several notable contributions follow. First, on the systemic level, Pollins (2008) advances Modelski and Thompson's (1996) work on leadership cycle theory, finding that rhythms in the global economy are associated with the rise and fall of a pre-eminent power and the often bloody transition from one pre-eminent leader to the next. As such, exogenous shocks such as economic crises could usher in a redistribution of relative power (see also Gilpin. 1981) that leads to uncertainty about power balances, increasing the risk of miscalculation (Feaver, 1995). Alternatively, even a relatively certain redistribution of power could lead to a permissive environment for conflict as a rising power may seek to challenge a declining power (Werner. 1999). Separately, Pollins (1996) also shows that global economic cycles combined with parallel leadership cycles impact the likelihood of conflict among major, medium and small powers, although he suggests that the causes and connections between global economic conditions and security conditions remain unknown. Second, on a dyadic level, Copeland's (1996, 2000) theory of trade expectations suggests that 'future expectation of trade' is a significant variable in understanding economic conditions and security behaviour of states. He argues that interdependent states are likely to gain pacific benefits from trade so long as they have an optimistic view of future trade relations. However, if the expectations of future trade decline, particularly for difficult [end page 213] to replace items such as energy resources, the likelihood for conflict increases, as states will be inclined to use force to gain access to those resources. Crises could potentially be the trigger for decreased trade expectations either on its own or because it triggers protectionist moves by interdependent states.4 Third, others have considered the link between economic decline and external armed conflict at a national level. Blomberg and Hess (2002) find a strong correlation between internal conflict and external conflict, particularly during periods of economic downturn. They write, The linkages between internal and external conflict and prosperity are strong and mutually reinforcing. Economic conflict tends to spawn internal conflict, which in turn returns the favour. Moreover, the presence of a recession tends to amplify the extent to which international and external conflicts self-reinforce each other. (Blomberg & Hess, 2002. p. 89) Economic decline has also been linked with an increase in the likelihood of terrorism (Blomberg, Hess, & Weerapana, 2004), which has the capacity to spill across borders and lead to external tensions. Furthermore, crises generally reduce the popularity of a sitting government. “Diversionary theory" suggests that, when facing unpopularity arising from economic decline, sitting governments have increased incentives to fabricate external military conflicts to create a 'rally around the flag' effect. Wang (1996), DeRouen (1995). and Blomberg, Hess, and Thacker (2006) find supporting evidence showing that economic decline and use of force are at least indirectly correlated. Gelpi (1997), Miller (1999), and Kisangani and Pickering (2009) suggest that the tendency towards diversionary tactics are greater for democratic states than autocratic states, due to the fact that democratic leaders are generally more susceptible to being removed from office due to lack of domestic support. DeRouen (2000) has provided evidence showing that periods of weak economic performance in the United States, and thus weak Presidential popularity, are statistically linked to an increase in the use of force. In summary, recent economic scholarship positively correlates economic integration with an increase in the frequency of economic crises, whereas political science scholarship links economic decline with external conflict at systemic, dyadic and national levels.5 This implied connection between integration, crises and armed conflict has not featured prominently in the economic-security debate and deserves more attention. This observation is not contradictory to other perspectives that link economic interdependence with a decrease in the likelihood of external conflict, such as those mentioned in the first paragraph of this chapter. [end page 214] Those studies tend to focus on dyadic interdependence instead of global interdependence and do not specifically consider the occurrence of and conditions created by economic crises. As such, the view presented here should be considered ancillary to those views.



Download 0.89 Mb.

Share with your friends:
1   ...   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   ...   27




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page