Growth and Poverty in Developing Countries



Download 1.01 Mb.
Page1/6
Date28.05.2018
Size1.01 Mb.
#52330
  1   2   3   4   5   6
Growth and Poverty in Developing Countries*

Montek S. Ahluwalia, Nicholas G. Carter and Hollis B. Chenery

Development Policy Staff, The World Bank,


Washington, DC 20433, USA Received December 1978

(from Journal of Development Economics 6 (1979) 299-341 © North-Holland Publishing Company)

Despite the developing countries’ impressive aggregate growth of the past 25 years, its benefits have only reached the poor to a very limned degree. Not only have the poorest countries grown relatively slowly, but growth processes are such that within most developing countries, the incomes of the poor increase much less than the average Although many policies have been proposed to counter these trends, little has been done to estimate the possibilities for significantly reducing world poverty within a reasonable period This paper develops a quantitative framework to project levels of poverty under different assumptions about GNP growth, population growth and changes in income distribution Although the interactions among development processes and policy instruments arc not modelled in any detail, the results serve to clarify the nature of the problem The policy simulations demonstrate that the elimination of absolute poverty by the end of this century is a highly unlikely prospect, even to achieve a substantial reduction will require a combination of policies designed to accelerate the growth of poor countries, to distribute the benefits of growth more equitably, and to reduce population increase.

1. Introduction

Although the output of the world economy has expanded at an unpre­cedented rate in the past quarter century, the benefits of growth have only reached the world's poor to a very limited degree. This is not due to any failure of developing countries as a group to share in the general economic expansion. Their income per capita rose by almost 3 percent per year over this period - considerably faster than in the past. The failure lies in the distributional pattern of past growth, which has left the poorest groups largely outside the sphere of economic expansion and material improvements.

There are two aspects to this phenomenon. First, the impressive growth record of the Third World as a whole conceals the fact that most of the poorest countries, containing the principal concentrations of the world's poor, have experienced lesser increases. Second, and equally important, there is mounting evidence that the growth processes under way in most develop­ing countries are such that incomes of the poorer groups increase more slowly than the average.

International debate has centered around the design of policies to offset these trends. Proponents of a New International Economic Order consider the major objective to be the acceleration of growth in developing countries, with special concessions to the poorest among them. Others give greater weight to policies to improve the internal distribution of income, including direct measures to satisfy the basic needs of the poorest groups. These issues have been discussed so far in largely qualitative terms with little attempt to translate global targets for the eradication of poverty into more specific strategies whose feasibility can be examined.

The present paper suggests a quantitative framework for such an analysis and derives some preliminary conclusions from it.'Although there is not yet an adequate statistical basis for a formal analysis of the key relationships involved, there has been considerable progress in the past few years in several areas: (a) the definition and measurement of the incidence of poverty, using both physical and monetary indexes, (b) securing internationally comparable data on income levels, based on purchasing power comparisons, (c) measurement of the distribution of income and consumption within developing countries.

Our study is in three parts: (I) estimation of the extent of absolute poverty in developing countries and of the relationship between income distribution and rising levels of output (section 2). (II) analysis of past trends in growth and poverty in a representative group of countries and of the implications of projecting these trends on the basis of present policies (section 3). (Ill) a consideration of possible improvements on this performance through acce­lerating income growth, improving its distribution and reducing fertility (section 4). We conclude with a comparison of alternative approaches to poverty reduction and their implications for national and international action. Despite the tentative nature of some of the underlying assumptions, it demonstrates that a combination of several approaches and of national and international action is more likely to succeed in reducing poverty than exclusive reliance on any one of them.



2. The dimensions of global poverty

This section attempts to evaluate the scale of poverty in the developing world and the available evidence on the effect of growth on poverty. The analysis is based on a sample of 36 countries which are listed below in table 1. The sample is broadly representative of developing countries with mixed or market-oriented economies. They span the wide range of income levels observed in the developing world and reflect ils distribution by broad geographic regions. Together, the countries in our sample account for about 80 percent of the population of the developing world, excluding China.1



2.1 Defining absolute poverty

The First step in measuring the scale of poverty is to establish a common poverty line to be applied across countries. It is self-evident that such a definition is necessarily arbitrary. Attempts to define absolute poverty in terms of some objectively determinate minimum level of consumption that is necessary for continued survival' do not escape this problem, since the notion of continued survival is undefined. Ai the very least we would need to specify survival through some given life expectancy in a given environment. Present levels of life expectancy in most developing countries are quite low and do not provide a basis for defining minimum requirements. Increases in life expectancy will require higher levels of real consumption including not only better food intake, but also a better general environment for health and nutrition.

Not only is the notion of a biologically determined absolute poverty level imprecise, it is in any case wrong to think that poverty should be defined solely in terms of biological requirements. Ultimately, concepts such as poverty lines are operationally meaningful only when they acquire some social reality, (hat is, when there exists a sufficient social concensus that a particular level of living represents an objective which claims a high social priority. Once we recognize that acceptability by contemporary social standards is a key requirement, it follows that poverty lines used in national policy debates will vary across countries, reflecting differences in levels of economic, social and political development. By the same token, they will also change over time.

For these reasons any effort to define a poverty line to be applied across countries and over lime must be approached with caution. We have concluded, however, that with all its limitations such a measure can provide a useful basis for international policy. For this purpose, it is less important that the poverty line correspond to some objective criteria for minimal levels than that the absolute level chosen be conservative and roughly comparable across countries. In this paper we have based our definition on the poverty lines which have been used in India, which is the largest and one of the best studied developing countries.



Table 1

Simple panel: Per capita income, population and poverty. a

Country b

1975 GNP per capita c




Percentage of population in poverty in 1975

at official exchange rates

using Kravis adjustment factors

Population 1975 (millions)

using Kravis adjustment factor

using official exchange rates

Group 4 (under $350 ICP)

(1) Bangladesh

72

200

80.7

64

60

(2) Ethiopia

81

213

27.3

68

62

(3) Burma

88

237

30.9

65

56

(4) Indonesia

90

280

130.0

59

62

(5) Uganda

115

280

11.5

55

45

(6) Zaire

105

281

20.6

53

49

(7) Sudan

112

281

18.1

54

47

(8) Tanzania

118

297

14.8

51

46

(9) Pakistan

121

299

73.0

43

34

(10) India

102

300

599.4

46




Subtotal

99

284

1006.3

51

49

Group B ($350-$750)

(11) Kenya

161

413

13.4

55

48

(12) Nigeria

176

433

75.3

35

27

(13) Philippines

182

469

41.5

33

29

(14) Sri Lanka

185

471

14.1

14

10

(15) Senegal

227

550

4.3

35

29

(16) Egypt

238

561

37.2

20

14

(17) Thailand

237

584

41.6

32

23

(18) Ghana

255

628

9.8

25

19

(19) Morocco

266

643

17.3

26

16

(20) Ivory Coast

325

695

5.9

25

14

Subtotal

209

511

261.4

31

24

Group C (greater than $750)

(21) Korea

325

797

34.1

8

6

(22) Chile

386

798

10.6

11

9

(23) Zambia

363

798

4.9

10

7

(24) Columbia

352

851

24.8

19

14

(25) Turkey

379

914

39.7

14

11

(26) Tunisia

425

992

5.7

10

9

(27) Malaysia

471

1006

12.2

12

8

(28) Taiwan

499

1075

16 1

5

4

(29) Guatemala

497

1128

5.5

10

9

(30) Brazil

509

1136

106.8

IS

8

(31) Peru

503

1183

15.3

18

15

(32) Iran

572

1257

33.9

13

8

(33) Mexico

758

1429

59.6

14

10

(34) Yugoslavia

828

1701

21.3

5

4

(35) Argentina

1097

2094

24.9

S

3

(36) Venezuela

1288

2286

12.2

9

5

Subtotal

577

1220

427.6

13

8

Total

237

555

1695.3

38

35

a Sources: GNP and population from World Bank Data Bank. Kravis adjustment factors from Kravis, Heston and Summers (1978a).

b Countries ordered by 1975 GNP per capita adjusted by Kravis factor.

c In 1970 US $.

There is an extensive literature on the measurement of poverty in India and a variety of poverty lines have been proposed, some of which have received official sanction. The most widely used poverty line is defined by the total consumption expenditure needed to ensure a daily supply of 2250 calories per person, given the observed expenditure patterns of the Indian population.2 Estimates of the extent of poverty in terms of this standard vary from year to year, but most estimates range between 40 and 50 percent of the total population. For our study we have adopted an intermediate position, setting the poverty level to be applied across countries as the income per head accruing to the forty-fifth percentile (approximately! of the Indian population. Application of this essentially South Asian standard across all developing countries yields estimates of poverty that arc con­servative in the sense of understating the extent of the problem by standards appropriate for richer countries.

Having chosen a poverty line, the next step is lo apply it in such a way as to ensure comparability across countries. The use of official exchange rates to define equivalent levels of expenditure in different countries does not ensure equivalent levels of real purchasing power. We have attempted to overcome this problem by using 'equivalent purchasing power conversion ratios' estimated by Kravis and associates from data collected by the United Nations International Comparison Project (ICP).3 Using these ratios, we can convert the per capita GNP levels in each country into GNP per capita measured in dollars of 1970 U.S. prices hereafter called ICP dollars. The resulting estimates are shown in table I. Our poverty line is easily calculated given the income distribution for India for 1975 and its estimated level of per capita GNP in ICP dollars. We have chosen a poverty line of 200 ICP dollars - the level of the 46th percentile which is then applied to the income distribution and per capita GNP data for other countries to estimate the extent of poverty in each case.4

This income-based approach to defining poverty makes no explicit allow­ance for the achievement of minimum levels for essential public services such as health, education, access to clean water and sanitation. These are fundamental elements in a more complete definition of poverty that are of crucial importance in designing a balanced program of poverty alleviation. but they remain outside the present analysis.



2.2. The extent of poverty in developing countries

The procedure just described enables us to estimate the extent of poverty in each country using an income level that reflects comparable levels of purchasing power. These estimates are reported in the fourth column of table 1. For purposes of comparison, we have also estimated the extent of poverty in our sample without the conversion ratios. In this case, we measure per capita GNP for each country in US dollars by converting at official exchange rates, calculate the income level of the 46th percentile in India and apply this level to the data for all other countries. These estimates arc shown in the last column of table 1. Since in each case the poverty line is based on the income of the same percentile of the Indian population, the difference between the two estimates lies in the extent to which poverty in other countries is altered relative to India.

In general, we find that the use of purchasing power ratios reduces the differences between the incidence of poverty in middle and higher income countries compared to the low income countries. The use of ICP dollars also raises the estimates of poverty relative to India in the low income countries. This rise reflects the fact that the Kravis purchasing power ratios suggest that GNP levels in both groups of countries are overstated relative to India.5

The major features of global poverty as revealed in the estimates based on purchasing power ratios correspond broadly to other estimates.6 Almost 40 percent of the population of the developing countries live in absolute poverty defined in terms of income levels that are insufficient to provide adequate nutrition by South Asian standards. The bulk of the poor are in the poorest countries: in South Asia, Indonesia, and sub-Saharan Africa. These countries account for two-thirds of the total population and well over three-fourths of the population in poverty. The incidence of poverty is 60 percent or more in countries having the lowest levels of real GNP.

Although the incidence of poverty is much lower for the middle income developing countries in our sample, our estimates of poverty in this group of countries increases from 24 to 31 percent when purchasing power ratios are used to estimate GNP. There is a similar increase in the high income group from 8 to 13 percent.

It is interesting to compare our estimates of absolute poverty to those reported for selected Latin American countries in a recent joint study by the Economic Commission for Latin America and the World Bank.7 This study estimates a much higher incidence of poverty in Latin America around 40 percent for the region as a whole but this results from the adoption of poverty lines that are significantly higher than those derived from South Asia. For example, the food budget was geared to a higher minimum nutritional level and was constrained to ensure some minimum consumption of higher value foods (meat, fruit, eggs and milk).8 The food budget thus obtained was used to define two different poverty lines: a destitution line", defined as income equal to the food budget, and a “poverty line”, defined as income equal to twice the food budget to allow for non-food expenditures. Estimates of the extent of poverty in the Latin American countries in our sample are broadly in line with Altimir's estimates of the extent of destitution (about 19 percent of the population of Latin America). Furthermore, projections using either method show little prospective decline in absolute poverty with present trends.



2.3. Poverty and growth: A review of evidence

The extent of poverty in any country depends upon two factors - the average level of income and the degree of inequality in its distribution. Although the estimates of income growth are relatively good, we have little reliable information on how the distribution of income has changed over time. Systematic time series data based on reliable sources and using comparable concepts are simply not available. At most there is a handful of countries for which we have observations for 2 or more years spanning a decade or so.

In the absence of time series data for individual countries any assessment of changes in the distribution of income accompanying development in the past must be based on what can be inferred from cross-country data. This evidence has been extensively studied in recent years and a brief summary of the findings is presented below.

The central theme in the continuing debate on trends in income distri­bution is whether development in the past has been accompanied by such an increase in inequality that the poor have benefited relatively little from overall growth. Much of this debate has its origin in the classical contri­butions of Kuznets (1955, 1963), who hypothesized that the process of development was likely to be accompanied by a substantial increase in inequality, which would reverse itself only at a relatively advanced stage. Kuznets’ original speculation was based on fragmentary historical data for the now developed countries, but in its later development, especially at the hands of subsequent contributors, the investigation of this hypothesis has relied almost entirely upon cross-country evidence. A number of studies -Adelman and Morris (1973), Paukert (1973), Chenery and Syrquin (1975) and Ahluwalia (1976) - using different, and progressively more reliable sets of cross-country data, have reported confirmation of the hypothesis to some degree.9 The average pattern discerned in the data is one of significant increase in inequality as income levels rise from the least developed to about US S600 per capita in 1975 prices.10



The extent of the increase in relative inequality reported by different authors varies substantially. At one extreme, Adelman and Morns (1973) have argued that the cross-country data suggest that economic growth will be accompanied by a process of prolonged absolute impoverishment for large sections of the population. Others, such as Ahluwalia (1976), have argued that although the cross-country evidence points to increasing inequality in the early stages, this does not completely offset the effect of growth. Income levels of the poorer quintiles are likely to rise, but much more slowly than the average.

Fig. 1. The Kuznets curve with country observation.

The limited time series evidence provides some support for Ahluwalia’s conclusion. There are a number of countries for which estimates arc available of the distribution of income (or consumption) at two points in time spanning about 10 years in each case. While many of these countries appear to show some decline in the shares of the poorer quintiles over lime, in no case is this decline in shares sufficiently sleep to offset the recorded growth in mean incomes.11 Some of this evidence is discussed below.

A simplified representation of the Kuznets effect is given in fig. 1, which plots the per capita income of the top 40 percent of the population against that of the bottom 60 percent. Lines of constant per capita income appear as downward sloping straight lines. Ahluwalia's estimate of the Kuznets curve in these dimensions appears as a curve with maximum inequality in the vicinity of 800 ICP dollars (1970 prices) Between the income levels of 200 and 800 dollars the share of the lower 60 percent declines from 32 percent to 23 percent of the national income. A country that followed this average relation would have about 80 percent of the increment accruing to the upper 40 percent of its citizens and quite modest increases for (he remaining groups.12

This average relationship can be compared with the observed movement of individual countries over specified periods of time, as shown by the arrows in fig. 1. These observations relate to a relatively short time period typically 10 years - and the data are often not strictly comparable for a given country. Nevertheless, the broad picture of intertemporal movements is generally consistent with the average cross-country path indicated by the Kuznets curve. The underlying observations for each country do not show any case of a decline in the per capita income of the lowest quintile.

It is important to emphasize that the average cross-country relationship should not be interpreted as an iron law. Individual countries that are able to establish the preconditions for a more egalitarian distribution of income and to stimulate growth in such a policy environment, as illustrated by Yugoslavia, Taiwan and Korea, may well be able to avoid or moderate the phase of increasing inequality. But there are a number of reasons why such a pattern is likely to emerge with a continuation of past policies, especially in the non-socialist countries characterized by sharp inequalities in the initial distribution of productive wealth (including land). For one thing, develop­ment typically involves a shift of population from the low income, slower growing agricultural sector to the high income, faster growing modern sector. This process, which is central to the dual economy theories of Lewis (1954) and Fei and Ranis (1964), can be shown to generate a phase of widening inequality.13 This is especially true when the growth of the modern sector takes an increasingly capital intensive form, as in Mexico and Brazil, with incomes per person employed rising relatively rapidly but with a limited increase in employment. It is less true of the more labor intensive form, illustrated by Taiwan and Korea, which is characterized by high rates of absorption of labor and a more rapid approach to full employment. Policy clearly has an important role in determining which form predominates.

There are several other factors that contribute to widening inequality. Economic growth is likely to produce a more rapid rise in the demand for skilled labor compared to unskilled labor, leading to widening inequality in the early stages, when the supply of skilled labor expands relatively slowly. These disequalizing factors are often exacerbated by an institutional and policy framework that is biased in favor of the modern, urban sectors of the economy, leading to an excessive flow of resources to these sectors, and increasing the incentives for capital intensive production.

Combining the available evidence with these a priori considerations, we conclude that the most likely outcome associated with economic growth in poor countries is some increase in inequality. The projections discussed below adopt this assumption in the Base Case but depart from it in considering the effects of improved distributional policies.

The use of the Kuznets curve in projections also implies that the distribution of income will improve in countries with a per capita income above 800 ICP dollars without specifying the effort required to redirect government policies. Needless to say, we cannot assume that this improve­ment will take place automatically. The low inequality observed in the developed countries today is as much the result-of institutional evolution resulting from particular historical and political factors as of their level of development. It has been argued by Bacha (1977) that the observed reduction in inequality in the developed countries over the first half of this century arose from social and political changes following the first world war that are not likely to be replicated in countries approaching industrial maturity today.14 We note that of the countries in Group C of table 1, all of which are past the turning point estimated from cross-country data, only Taiwan shows some evidence of experiencing the second phase of the Kuznets curve.

However, although our projections may be overoptimistic about future developments in countries approaching industrial maturity, this assumption does not affect our projections of global poverty.




Download 1.01 Mb.

Share with your friends:
  1   2   3   4   5   6




The database is protected by copyright ©ininet.org 2024
send message

    Main page