Regardless of alternate energy efforts oil dependence will continue to increase
Joseph J. Romm and Charles B. Curtis, 4-96 Atlantic Monthly
What is the appropriate national response to the re-emerging energy-security threat? Abroad the Department of Energy has been working hard to expand sources of oil outside the Persian Gulf region--in the former Soviet Union, for example--and to encourage the privatization of the oil companies in Mexico and other Latin American countries.
At home the DOE is encouraging greater production by providing royalty relief in the deep waters of the Gulf of Mexico and similar incentives, so that the industry can drill wells that otherwise would not be cost-effective. The DOE is working to reduce the cost for the industry to comply with federal regulations. Finally, the department is spending tens of millions of dollars a year to develop new technologies that will lower the cost of finding and extracting oil--for example, using advanced computing to model oil fields. Still, few expect to reverse the decade-long decline in U.S. oil production. Some would open the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge to drilling, a plan the Clinton Administration has opposed on environmental grounds, but not even that would change our forecasted oil dependency much. This is true even using earlier, more optimistic estimates that the refuge could provide 300,000 barrels of oil a day for thirty years. The EIA projects that within ten to fifteen years the United States will probably be importing thirty times as much--some 10 million barrels of crude oil a day, even if the decline in other domestic production levels off in the next few years.
Increasing domestic supply, although it may help to slow the rising tide of imports, cannot itself reverse the major trend. And reversing the nation's ever-increasing demand for oil would be difficult. The country is in no mood to enact higher energy taxes in order to bring our energy markets into better balance. To most people, an increase in gasoline taxes of even a few cents a gallon--let alone the amount needed to have a noticeable impact on consumption--is anathema. Similarly, Congress is in no mood for a regulatory approach, such as mandating increased fuel efficiency for cars.
Oil dependence inevitable-Oil imports will increase to 60% in ten years
Joseph J. Romm and Charles B. Curtis, 4-96 Atlantic Monthly
The growing dependence on imported oil in general and Persian Gulf oil in particular has several potentially serious implications for the nation's economic and national security. First, the United States is expected to be importing nearly 60 percent of its oil by ten years from now, with roughly a third of that oil coming from the Persian Gulf. Our trade deficit in oil is expected to double, to $100 billion a year, by that time--a large and continual drag on our economic health. To the extent that the Gulf's recapture of the dominant share of the global oil market will make price increases more likely, the U.S. economy is at risk. Although oil imports as a percent of gross domestic product have decreased significantly in the past decade, our economic vulnerability to rapid increases in the price of oil persists. Since 1970 sharp increases in the price of oil have always been followed by economic recessions in the United States.Second, the Persian Gulf nations' oil revenues are likely to almost triple, from $90 billion a year today to $250 billion a year in 2010--a huge geopolitical power shift of great concern, especially since some analysts predict increasing internal and regional pressure on Saudi Arabia to alter its pro-Western stance. This represents a $1.5 trillion increase in wealth for Persian Gulf producers over the next decade and a half. That money could buy a tremendous amount of weaponry, influence, and mischief in a chronically unstable region. And the breakup of the Soviet Union, coupled with Russia's difficulty in earning hard currency, means that for the next decade and beyond, pressure will build to make Russia's most advanced military hardware and technical expertise available to well-heeled buyers.
The final piece in the geopolitical puzzle is that during the oil crisis of the 1970s the countries competing with us for oil were our NATO allies, but during the next oil crisis a new, important complication will arise: the competition for oil will increasingly come from the rapidly growing countries of Asia. Indeed, in the early 1970s East Asia consumed well under half as much oil as the United States, but by the time of the next crisis East Asian nations will probably be consuming more oil than we do.
AT: Oil Dependency Kills Economy
2. Inevitable-Total consumption not oil dependence will hurt the economy
Michael A. Toman, '02 The Brookings Institution
http://www.brookings.edu/articles/2002/spring_energy_toman.aspx?p=1
The Bush administration favors increasing domestic energy production to reduce dependence on foreign oil, along with some limited efforts to expand energy efficiency and alternative energy resources. Following the release of the administration's plan, legislation was introduced in the House of Representatives to offer new tax breaks for domestic energy, including petroleum, and to open the Alaskan National Wildlife Refuge to oil exploration and production. Critics of the plan argue against ANWR drilling and for greater efforts to improve energy efficiency (in particular, vehicle efficiency), as well as to develop and expand the long-term use of domestic renewables. Understanding the logic of the international oil security problem helps one sort through this welter of conflicting proposals. As noted, increasing U.S. domestic petroleum output will do relatively little to enhance energy security. A big increase in U.S. output could heighten competition for OPEC in the short to medium term, thereby moderating oil prices somewhat. But U.S. oil production is simply too high-cost (and reserves too limited) for increases in domestic output to affect OPEC much, especially over the long haul. Moreover, while increased U.S. output might fractionally reduce the probability and severity of disturbances in the world oil market, it will also increase vulnerability to the extent that it helps keep prices down and discourages longer-term reductions in the oil-intensity of overall economic activity. Again, the problem is total consumption relative to economic activity, not import dependence or sources of imports. Finally, the social cost of expanding domestic supplies by developing higher-cost resources and granting more indirect subsidies is likely to be considerable.
Economic Independence Good
Oil independence increase economic instability
Kevin A. Hassett Aug. 2007
Kevin A. Hassett is a senior fellow and director of economic policy studies at AEI. Gilbert E. Metcalf is a professor of economics at Tufts University and a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic Research.
It is widely held that the United States must reduce its reliance on foreign oil. The concern over our vulnerability to supply disruption by the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) is understandable, given the fact that the United States imports over 60 percent of the oil it consumes each year. Of the oil we import, 40 percent comes from OPEC countries, and nearly half of that from the Persian Gulf region. Many are also concerned that oil monies help countries like Iran pursue activities that are contrary to American foreign policy.
As a response to these concerns, current tax policy promotes domestic oil and gas production in a variety of ways. We provide a production tax credit for "non-conventional oil" (essentially a subsidy for coalbed methane), generous depreciation for intangible expenses associated with drilling, and generous percentage depletion allowances for oil and gas. In addition, the George W. Bush administration has consistently lobbied to allow additional drilling on the Alaskan North Slope.
This supply response ignores a fundamental fact: oil is essentially a generic commodity priced on world markets. Even if the United States were to produce all the oil it consumes, it would still be vulnerable to oil price fluctuations. A supply reduction by any major producer would raise prices of domestic oil just as readily as it raises prices of imported oil. In addition, if the United States reduces its demand for oil from countries such as Iran, it has little effect on Iran, as that country can just sell oil to other countries at the prevailing world price. Indeed, this effect has been made abundantly clear by historical experience. The United States has cut its dependence on Iranian oil to zero, buying no oil directly from that nation since 1991. Despite the U.S. import ban, Iran was the world's fourth-largest net oil exporter in 2005.[1]
A policy of energy independence that depends on boosting domestic oil and gas supplies through subsidies has several defects. First, subsidies reduce production costs and so do nothing to discourage oil consumption. Second, the policy encourages the consumption of high-cost domestic oil in place of low-cost foreign oil. A policy to encourage the United States to use up domestic reserves and thus become increasingly vulnerable in the future to foreign supply dislocations seems especially peculiar to us. Third, it is expensive. The five-year cost simply for the incentives mentioned above totals nearly $10 billion, according to the most recent administration budget submission.
Assuming reliance on oil is unattractive. A clear sign that policy is headed in the wrong direction is the high and even recently increasing dependence on oil of the U.S. economy. Petroleum comprised nearly 48 percent of primary energy consumption in the United States in 1977. Since this peak, it fell to a low of 38 percent in 1995 before inching up to just over 40 percent in 2005.[2] Even going back to 1977, the 16 percent drop in the oil share from its peak to 2005 falls far short of the percentage reduction in oil share of other developed countries. The United Kingdom, for example, has reduced its oil share from a peak of 50 percent to just under 36 percent. France has reduced its oil share by 48 percent, and Germany by 22 percent. In Asia, Japan has reduced its oil share by 39 percent, and even China has reduced its oil share by more than has the United States, with a 26 percent reduction. Our current policies are leaving us increasingly vulnerable relative to other major oil-consuming nations.
One might argue that because the United States is such a large producer of petroleum products--we are the third-largest supplier behind Russia and Saudi Arabia--our domestic supply incentives help reduce the world price of oil. Our efforts, however, are but a drop in the bucket. One of us has estimated that the domestic oil production incentives in our tax code have lowered world oil prices by less than one-half of 1 percent.[3] To summarize, energy independence as popularly construed has little economic content. If reliance on oil is a problem, then supply subsidies make little sense, as they just encourage additional reliance on oil.
Share with your friends: |